[Company Logo Image]     Structural Transformation of Bourgeoisie

 

Home
News
Analysis
History
Marxism for Beginners
Discussion Forum
Feedback
Site Map
Search

 

The Structural Transformation of the Bourgeoisie in the Third World

[The bourgeoisie] creates a world after its own image.

The Communist Manifesto

 

Table of Contents

Introduction

A Short Note on the Theoretical Apparatus

The Era of Bourgeois-Democratic Revolutions in the West

 

The Era of Bourgeois-Democratic Revolutions in the Third World – In the Mirror of the First World

The First Wave of Popular Nationalist Mobilisation in the Third World

The Second Wave of Popular Nationalist Mobilization in the Third World

Ideological Foundations of the Second Wave

Rapprochement and Compromise

The Incomplete Bourgeois-Democratic Movement in Pakistan

Colonialism and Pakistan

Independence

The Calm Before the Storm: 1947 to 1968

The Anti-Ayub Movement and the New Challengers

Anatomy of the Pakistan Peoples Party 

Pakistani Nationalism  

Policies Towards the Establishment

Policies Towards the National-Bourgeoisie 

Policies Towards the Working Class

The State

Foreign Policy

The Social Composition of the PPP

Transformation of the Pakistani National-Bourgeoisie to Conservative Old Age

Conclusion  40

Introduction

In the last two or three decades politics in the Third World have undergone a marked and visible structural transformation.  Historian Eric Hobsbawm notes,

 

…none of the successful movements of liberation in the backward world before the 1970s were inspired or achieved by traditional or neo-traditional ideologies.  …Fundamentalist religion as a major force of successful mass mobilisation belongs to the last decades of the twentieth century. (Hobsbawm 1994 pg. 201, 202)

 

Since the religiously inspired Iranian revolution in 1979, political movements espousing Jihad have become increasingly influential and visible in Islamic countries.  Similarly, in Latin America movements based on liberation theology have emerged and gained influence in the last quarter of the twentieth century.  Even in secular and democratic India, the Bharatia Janata Party (BJP) has been able to win the popular vote and form the central government.  After the events of September 11th and the resulting “War on Terrorism”, these religious ‘anti-modernist’, ‘anti-secular’, and ‘anti-democratic’ movements are receiving more and more attention in academic and popular circles.  The growing impact of these movements deserves serious attention; however, much of what is written is descriptive and fails to explain the rise of these political movements based on traditional ideologies in historical context. This book argues that the structural transformation of politics is a product of the dialectics of the life cycle of the bourgeoisie within Third World countries.

 

Marxists have shown that the life cycle of the bourgeoisie in Europe passed through three phases of development: an adolescent phase, a mature revolutionary phase, and finally a conservative phase.  The bourgeoisie in Europe emerged as a class in the 16th century within the context of a feudal monarchy.  It rose to revolutionary maturity in the 18th and 19th century resulting in an era of bourgeois-democratic revolutions across Europe.  Thereafter, the bourgeoisie perceived that its interests were more threatened by a workers revolution than by feudal restoration.  As a result towards the end of the 19th century, and especially after the Paris Commune of 1871, the bourgeoisie in Europe became a conservative class. 

 

In the second section, the book will examine whether the life cycle of the bourgeoisie in the Third World mirrors, with certain modifications, the above-mentioned development of the bourgeoisie in Europe.  On this basis the book attempts to delineate the principle phases in the development of the bourgeoisie in the Third World: the adolescent phase, the mature and revolutionary phase, and finally the conservative phase.  Briefly, the book argues that the bourgeoisie within various regions of the third world emerged as a class in the 18th and 19th century within the context of colonial rule.  Just as the bourgeoisie in Europe outgrew its womb of feudal society, similarly the bourgeoisie within various regions of the Third World outgrew the womb of colonialism.  In the 20th century this class rose to revolutionary maturity resulting in an era of anti-colonial movements, revolts, and reforms in the Third World.  This era of popular nationalist mass mobilisations burst forward with the end of the First World War and lasted till the 1980s.  Certain authors divide this period into further parts:  The first wave of mass mobilisation began at the end of the First World War and culminated in the creation of independent states across the Third World, and the second wave began in the mid-twentieth century and ended around the 1980s.  After the 1980s the bourgeoisie in various regions of the Third World exhausted its revolutionary potential.  On the whole, by this time the bourgeoisie in the Third World perceived that its interests were more threatened by a workers revolt than by Western hegemony.  Thus, with the beginning of the conservative phase of the bourgeoisie in the Third World, the secular democratic popular nationalist mass mobilisations faded away.  Ironically, at this moment working class movements in all parts of the world were also decimated as a repercussion of the collapse of the Soviet Union.  Thus, in the last decades of the 20th century, the bourgeoisie within the Third World was no longer prepared to undertake the task of popular mass mobilisations against encroachments on national sovereignty by Western hegemony.  On the other hand, working class movement in the world were demoralised, devastated, and shattered by the collapse of the Soviet Union.  The eclipse of the nationalist mass mobilisations of the bourgeoisie and the socialist mass mobilisations of the working class created a political vacuum in which forces based on religious or traditional ideologies became increasingly visible resulting in the aforementioned structural transformation of politics in the Third World.

 

In the third section, the book investigates whether this framework of structural transformation helps to explain political developments in Pakistan.  In other words, the third section offers a microcosmic study of Pakistan in relation to the structural transformation of politics in the Third World.  In particular, the paper attempts to explain the rise and fall of the Pakistan Peoples Party in the context of the structural transformation of politics in the Third World.  The industrialisation during the so- called decade of development (General Ayub Khan 1958-1968) resulted in the mobilisation of new forces of change that were influenced by the sweeping waves of Afro-Arab and Asian unity.  Thus, the rise of the Pakistan Peoples Party coincided, mirrored, influenced, and was influenced by the second wave of popular nationalist mass mobilisations across the Third World.  Through the quasi-theocratic Zia era, the PPP retained its mass support.  Ironically, only with the restoration of democracy did the party begin to lose popular support creating an enormous political vacuum that no political force has, as yet, filled.  The decline in the ability of the PPP to spearhead the popular movement in Pakistan in the last decade of the twentieth century is indicative of the changing character of the bourgeoisie in that country.  In sum, the paper will examine whether the rise and fall of the PPP—that represented a bourgeois-democratic reform movement—is linked to the life-cycle of the bourgeoisie in the Third World as a whole.

 

A Short Note on the Theoretical Apparatus

 

A central term that requires clarification is the concept of class.  Class is a historically constituted relationship of a stratum of society to the means of production.  Since the relationship to the means of production conditions all social relations, therefore, class is the sum totality of all historically constituted social relations that are conditioned by the relation to the means of production.  The Marxist method of determining the class basis of a given political movement begins by first deconstructing the rhetoric to identify the principle demands of the movement in question.  These principle demands correspond to objective interests of particular classes in society.  Therefore, the analytical process of extrapolating the principle demands of a political movement to the objective interests of classes in society reveals the class basis of a political movement. 

 

Although the paper continuously uses the terms “the bourgeoisie in Europe” and “the bourgeoisie in the Third World”, the use of these terms is not meant to imply complete homogeneity of interests between or within the bourgeoisie of different nations, countries, states, and regions.  Naturally, the “bourgeoisie in Europe” and the “bourgeoisie in the third world” is not a class with a completely homogenous set of interests and views.  Nonetheless, the bourgeois class is identifiable as a stratum of society whose interests are connected with the preservation and promotion of private property and capital as the dominating form of economic intercourse.  Defined in this manner, the internal complexity caused by competition and antagonism between various conglomerates of bourgeois interests does not undermine the concept of the bourgeoisie as a class in history.  Thus, the author holds the view that it would be incorrect to conclude from the internal complexity of any social category, such as a class, that the social category itself does not exist.  In conclusion, while the bourgeoisie is an internally complex social category, it is nonetheless, discernable and identifiable with respect to other classes in society.        

 

The Era of Bourgeois-Democratic Revolutions in the West

 

In the early Nineteenth century Hegel introduced the profound and influential notion that human history represented an idea or consciousness in the process of dialectical motion.  Karl Marx and Fredrick Engels combined this notion of dialectics with Feuerbach’s materialism to develop a view of history that has come to be known as ‘dialectical materialism’.  Engels wrote in Ludwig Feuerbach,

 

The great basic thought that the world is not to be comprehended as a complex of ready-made things, but as a complex of processes, in which the things apparently stable, no less than their mind-images in our heads, the concepts, go through an uninterrupted change of coming into being and passing away...

 

For it [dialectical philosophy] nothing is final, absolute, sacred.  It reveals the transitory character of everything; nothing can endure before it except the uninterrupted process of becoming and of passing away, of endless ascendancy from the lower to the higher.  And dialectical philosophy itself is nothing more than the mere reflection of this process in the thinking brain. (Engels, Ludwig Feuerbach p.22)

 

Marx and Engels came to the conclusion that the dialectic of class struggle was the motor of history and declared, “the history of all hitherto existing societies is the history of class struggle” (Marx & Engels, 1983, pp. 204).  Thus, according to this dialectical view of history, classes were constantly in the process of coming into being and passing away, birth and death, generation and degeneration. Moreover, different modes of production and periods of history—primitive communism, slave, feudal, capitalist, or socialist—could be delineated in accordance with the class in power (Marx & Engels, German Ideology, pp. 48). 

 

Classical Marxism explained the history of Europe in this Hegelian dialectical schematic.  The history of the rise and fall of the revolutionary period of the bourgeoisie of Europe was eloquently captured in more contemporary style in the trilogy by Eric Hobsbawm entitled The Age of Revolutions 1962, The Age of Capital 1975, The Age of Empire 1987.  According to Marxists, the first elements of the modern bourgeoisie emerged from the chartered burghers of the fifteenth century and gained strength through the development of navigation and the exploration of new markets in newly acquired colonies of America, India, Africa, and China (Wolf 1982, Hobsbawm 1962, Wallerstein 1979). During the 16th century the bourgeoisie had not as yet become the dominant class but was gaining maturity within the womb of feudal society.  From the mid-seventeenth century to the late eighteenth century the big-bourgeoisie rose and built a world market for its goods thereby extending and consolidating its influence on the world stage. With the rise of the big-bourgeoisie the further growth of productive forces came into increasing contradiction with the dominant feudal relations. Feudal economic, political, and cultural institutions together with attitudes, ideas and relations had all become, in the words of Marx, “fetters on the further development of productive forces” (Marx & Engels, German Ideology, pp. 70).  This contradiction, that is the contradiction between the backward feudal relations of production and the highly developed capitalist productive forces, led to a period of political convulsions.  It resulted in an era of the bourgeois-democratic revolutions all over Europe.

 

For Marxists, the French Revolution of 1789 epitomised the classical form of the transition from feudalism to capitalism. France made a clean break with feudalism, the monarchy was overthrown in a bloody revolution, and feudal landholdings were broken up.  This revolutionary republican path later led to the materialization of a liberal democratic capitalism (Moore 1966).  The French Revolution and the ensuing Napoleonic wars propagated and proliferated the political, economic, cultural ideas of modern capitalism across the European continent. 

 

After a short period of peaceful development, another wave of bourgeois democratic upheavals simultaneously hit several European countries in the year 1848. But the year saw a curious new development. The proletariat as a political force also came to occupy the European revolutionary theatre.  Although the proletariat was as yet at a relatively infantile stage, nonetheless, it was far larger and more concentrated than it had been during the French Revolution, and therefore, a prominent contender for power. This third force competing for power against both the feudal lords and the bourgeoisie terrified the latter.  Alarmed by this new development even the hitherto revolutionary republican bourgeoisie in Paris ordered the shooting of workers in the June days of 1848. The conduct of classes during the upheavals of 1848 proved that the bourgeoisie was transformed from revolutionary youth to conservative old age under the impending threat of a workers revolution.  Thereafter the transition to capitalism in Europe did not proceed on the revolutionary republican path but proceeded through peaceful changes and reforms.  The transition to capitalism in Central and Eastern Europe occurred without a complete revolutionary break from feudalism.  At the time in these countries small bands of revolutionary intellectuals were hoping for the transfer of power to workers owing to the politicisation in the revolutionary atmosphere.  At the same time, the bourgeoisie feared the emergence of working class power and recoiled from the tasks of bourgeois-democratic liberation from feudalism.  Thus, during the transition to capitalism in Prussia and Central Europe, the feudal landholdings owned by the Junkers were not broken up.  Lenin called the latter path to capitalism the Junkers path.  The bourgeoisie colluded with feudal monarchies to introduce capitalist reforms by careful and gradual means.  Thus, the feudal monarchies of Central and Eastern Europe underwent a transition rather than a revolution.  Barrington Moore further developed this idea in his famous book The Social Roots of Dictatorship and Democracy and argued that whereas the revolutionary republican path lead to liberal democratic capitalism, the Junkers path always remained more susceptible to fascism and dictatorship (Moore 1966).

 

The Paris Commune of 1871 proved to be the final nail in the proverbial coffin of the youthful and revolutionary period of the bourgeoisie. Marx’s eloquent defence of the revolutionary workers of Paris in the Civil War in France argued that the Paris Commune of 1871 had completed the development of the bourgeois democratic republic in Europe.  Thereafter, the bourgeoisie of Europe was no longer a youthful and revolutionary class but a conservative force.  After the crushing of the Paris Commune a unique period of calm and peaceful development ensued (1872 to 1904). Lenin summed up this historical period by the phrase, “The West had finished with their bourgeois revolutions. The East had not yet risen to theirs.” (Lenin 1977, pg 18)

Figure 1: The Phases of Development of the Bourgeoisie in Europe

 

Adolescence                                                            Revolutionary         Conservative

(16th century to 1789)                                                           (1789 – 1871)         (1871 onwards)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 


16th century                                              1789         1848    1871            Present

 

The above figure, although admittedly a crude application of quantitative tools to understand qualitative phenomenon, nonetheless helps to simplify and explain the dialectic of development of the European bourgeoisie.  If one could quantify ‘revolutionary potential’ and plot it on an axis against the passage of time, the curve would roughly have an inverted U shape as shown above. The figure, as long as it is viewed with a little humour, helps to show that the bourgeoisie in Europe reached the pinnacle of its revolutionary maturity during the French revolution of 1789. The upheavals of 1848 occurred in the context of a more conservative bourgeoisie that feared a workers revolution.  On a world historic scale, the point around which the bourgeoisie swung from supporting, arousing, and leading revolutions to opposing and crushing them was 1848. The revolutionary workers of the Paris Commune of 1871 struggled in a period when the bourgeoisie feared a workers’ revolt more than it feared the forces of feudalism and reaction.  Therefore, the year of 1871 marks the end of the transition to bourgeois rule in Europe.  

 

In conclusion, the central factor that transformed the bourgeoisie in Europe from a revolutionary to a conservative force was the growth and developing of a revolutionary workers movement.  Fear of a workers revolt drove the bourgeoisie ever deeper into the arms of reaction. In accordance with this understanding of history one can delineate three periods in the development of the bourgeoisie of Europe.

 

1.        The first period of adolescence began with the birth of the bourgeoisie in the 15th and 16th century. During this period the bourgeoisie was a subjugated class struggling for power under feudalism. This period of subordination to feudalism came to close in the late 18th century (more specifically with the French Revolution of 1789).

 

2.        The second revolutionary period opened with the storming of the Bastille and the guns of the French Revolution 1789. This period of revolutionary upheavals and bourgeois-democratic revolutions lasts nearly a hundred years till the crushing of the Paris Commune in 1871. At the end of this period, the bourgeoisie emerged as the dominant class of Europe and the world and the political transformation from feudalism to capitalism was in the main complete.

 

3.        The third conservative period began after the crushing of the Paris Commune of 1871. The bourgeoisie of Europe passed from history as a revolutionary class. A period of relatively peaceful transformation replaced the earlier revolutionary epoch. The bourgeoisie was now a conservative force on the stage of world history.

 

This schematic of class struggle presented above is a deliberate simplification of the overall movement of classes during the transition of feudalism to capitalism.  The actual process of transformation from feudalism to capitalism abounds with entanglements, complications, twists and turns, incomplete transformations, and other unaccounted factors.  The actual process of history is always infinitely more colourful than the grey matter of theory that must inevitably be based on simplifications and generalisations. The above schematic is merely an attempt to summarize the very broad and general movement of class struggle during the period of capitalist development. 

 

 

The Era of Bourgeois-Democratic Revolutions in the Third WorldIn the Mirror of the First World

 

At the beginning of the 20th century much of what has come to be known today as the Third World was under colonial domination by a handful of European countries.  Britain and France, the major colonial powers, controlled most of Asia and Africa.  Holland, Portugal, and Belgium, the relatively smaller colonial powers, controlled another substantial portion of the world.  In the 20th century Japan joined the list of imperialist countries with the colonisation of parts of East Asia.  The expansion of trade into these ancient lands led to the creation and emergence of a ‘native’ bourgeoisie.  Political developments in the 20th century were shaped by the development of this native bourgeoisie in the Third World.

 

There were, however, two factors that distinguished the development of the bourgeoisie in the Third World from the development of its counterpart in Europe.  First, while the bourgeoisie in Europe emerged within and later struggled against feudal society, the bourgeoisie in the Third World emerged within and later struggled against colonial society.  In other words, the bourgeoisie in the Third World had to struggle against another advanced bourgeois force to gain power.  Second, this conflict between the bourgeoisie in the Third World and their former colonial rulers occurred in the context of the rivalry between the capitalist and socialist camp.  It comes as no surprise, therefore, that essentially bourgeois forces utilised socialist slogans in the Third World not only to appeal to their own people but also to obtain assistance from the Soviet Union in the struggle against Western hegemony. These two factors were instrumental in shaping the ideological, political, and organisational tools that the native bourgeoisie utilised in the process of its growth and development.

The First Wave of Popular Nationalist Mobilisation in the Third World

The first task that history bequeathed to the native bourgeoisie was the acquisition of independence from colonial rule.  The dislocation caused by the First World War and the international influence of the October revolution in Russia resulted in the first wave of popular nationalist mass mobilisation against colonialism.  Lenin in his writings on China characterised the bourgeoisie of the colonial countries as a “young revolutionary class”.  He wrote,

 

One is naturally inclined to compare the provisional President of the Republic in benighted, inert, Asiatic China with the presidents of various republics in Europe and America, in countries of advanced culture.  The presidents in those republics are all businessmen, agents or puppets of a bourgeoisie rotten to the core and besmirched from head to foot with mud and blood—not the blood of padishahs and emperors, but the blood of striking workers shot down in the name of progress and civilisation.  In those countries the presidents represent the bourgeoisie, which long ago renounced all the ideals of its youth, has thoroughly prostituted itself, sold itself body and soul to the millionaires and multimillionaries, to the feudal lords turned bourgeois, etc.

 

In China, the Asiatic provisional President of the Republic is a revolutionary democrat, endowed with the nobility and heroism of a class that is rising, not declining, a class that does not dread the future, but believes in it and fights for it selflessly, a class that does not cling to the maintenance and restoration of the past in order to safe-guard its privileges, but hates the past and knows how to cast off its dead and stifling decay (Lenin, 1977).

 

Similarly in his famous article Backward Europe and Advanced Asia Lenin wrote. 

 

In civilised and advanced Europe, with its highly developed machine industry, its rich, multiform culture and its constitutions, a point in history has been reached when the commanding bourgeoisie, fearing the growth and increasing strength of the proletariat, comes out in support of everything backward, moribund and medieval.  The bourgeoisie is living out its last days, and is joining with all obsolete and obsolescent forces in an attempt to preserve tottering wage-slavery.

 

Advanced Europe is commanded by a bourgeoisie which supports everything that is backward.  The Europe of our day is advanced not thank to, but in spite of, the bourgeoisie, for it is only the proletariat that is adding to the million-strong army of fighters for a better future.  It alone preserves and spreads implacable enmity towards backwardness, savagery, privilege, slavery and the humiliation of man by man.

 

In “advanced” Europe, the sole advanced class is the proletariat.  As for the living bourgeoisie, it is prepared to go to any length of savagery, brutality and crime in order to uphold dying capitalist slavery.

 

And a more striking example of this decay of the entire European bourgeoisie can scarcely be cited than the support it is lending to reaction in Asia in furtherance of the selfish aims of the financial manipulators and capitalist swindlers.

 

Everywhere in Asia a mighty democratic movement is growing, spreading and gaining in strength.  The bourgeoisie there is as yet siding with the people against reaction.  Hundreds of millions of people are awakening to life, light and freedom.  What delight this world movement is arousing in the hearts of all class-conscious workers, who know that the path to collectivism lies through democracy!  What sympathy for young Asia imbues all honest democrats!

 

 

All the commanders of Europe, all the European bourgeoisie are in alliance with all the forces of reaction and medievalism in China.

 

But all young Asia, that is, the hundreds of millions of Asian working people, has a reliable ally in the proletariat of all civilised countries.  No force on earth can prevent its victory, which will liberate both the peoples of Europe and the peoples of Asia (Lenin, May 10, 1913 CW vol. 19, pp. 99-100).

 

This notion proved correct when the nationalist movement in China exploded with student protests in Peking in May 1919 and eventually led to the creation of the Koamingtang (Nationalist) Party headed by Sun Yat Sen. Similarly Sarekat Islam, the principle national liberation organisation of Indonesia, was also influenced in the same period and eventually Sukarno emerged as the leader of the nationalists (Jansen, 1979, pp. 95-98).  In India, the All-India Congress was founded at the turn of the century and emerged at the head of a mass movement.  In Africa, Kwame Nkhruma and the Pan-Africanists emerged soon after as the principle representatives of anti-colonial nationalism on the continent (Basil Davidson 1980).  On the continent of Latin America, Spanish colonial rule had already been overthrown before the beginning of the 20th century and around twenty Latin republics were on their way towards the development of capitalist states (Hobsbawm, 1994, pp. 181).  Nonetheless, Latin America was not unaffected by the ripples of nationalist and revolutionary currents and student unrest in Cardoba Argentina in 1918 led to the strengthening of left-wing nationalist movements and all across Latin America.  Moctezuma and Emiliano Zapata became the symbols of this new upsurge (Hobsbawm, 1994, pp. 191).  In conclusion, all over Asia, Africa, and Latin America the anti-colonial nationalist movement emerged at the beginning of the 20th century.  On the whole, the principle objective of this first wave of mobilisation was to elevate the native bourgeoisie to the position of the ruling class within the context of their respective states. 

 

Post-war historians, especially those connected to Cambridge University, have highlighted the instrumental role of the native elite in colonial societies in organising an all-encompassing nationalist struggle (Seal, 1968).  Further, these historians have shown how these anti-colonial nationalist movements were ideologically committed to Western secular-democratic values including the preservation of private property.  While it is true that many of these political leaders utilised religious symbolism to arouse popular support, it would be incorrect to conclude from this observation that the driving force of these movements were traditional or neo-traditional ideas.  These movements were essentially inspired by the concept of nationalism.  Nationalism as a political tendency was distinct from movements inspired purely by religion.  Even where religious symbolism was utilised it was bent to meet the needs of the nationalism movement.  Thus, the use of religious symbolism represented political pragmatism whereas the actual goal of the movement was inspired by nationalism.  Elie Kedourie in Nationalism in Asia and Africa explains how the very fundamental concepts of the anti-colonial nationalist movement, such as the right of nations to self-determination, were based on, if not directly imported from, Western political understanding (Kedourie 1970, p. 28).  Moreover, the first generation of anti-colonial nationalist leaders were most often men either directly educated in the West or well versed in European political understanding.  For example, Sun Yat Sen of China, Ataturk of Turkey, Mohandas Karamchand Gandhi of India, Mohammed Ali Jinnah of Pakistan, Sukarno of Indonesia, Kwame Nkhruma of Ghana were all educated in the West.  These Western concepts of nationalism were utilised by the emerging bourgeoisie in the Third World to mobilise the general population, filling them with energy for independence, and in certain cases even calling them to arms (Albertini, 1961; Hobsbawm, 1994).  From the vast work of these historians it is not implausible to conclude that an emerging bourgeoisie in the colonies rose to revolutionary maturity and organised the anti-colonial struggle in the early 20th century. 

 

This first stage of struggle was brought to completion with the end of the Second World War and the process of decolonisation.  European empires, weakened from mutual exhaustion and destruction, could no longer hold on to their respective colonial possessions and the anti-colonial nationalist movements came to power in the immediate post-war period.  In a matter of a few years the number of internationally recognized independent states in Asia quintupled.  In Africa, where there had been only one state in 1939, there were now about fifty new internationally recognized independent states.  Latin America also witnessed the birth of a dozen new independent states.  In certain colonial states, especially those threatened by Japanese expansionism, the tasks of national liberation coalesced with the general anti-fascist war effort.  For example, in China, Vietnam, and Korea, the real or perceived failure of the native bourgeoisie to lead the national liberation movement and the international impact of the Soviet Union catapulted communist movements to the commanding heights of those societies.  On the whole, by the mid twentieth century the first and fundamental task of the anti-colonial movement, that is political independence from colonial rule, was on its way towards completion and the bourgeoisie in the colonised world was emerging to take power.

The Second Wave of Popular Nationalist Mobilization in the Third World

 

Although the process of decolonisation was well underway by 1950, nonetheless, the bourgeois-democratic emancipation in the Third World was not yet complete.  First, certain colonial powers simply refused to decolonise.  For example, Portugal and Belgium obstinately held on to their African colonies (Davidson, 1980).  Similarly the settler-colonies of Kenya, Algeria, and South Africa refused to widen the franchise of state power to include the African population (Davidson, 1980).  Second, in other newly formed countries, the first generation nationalist leaders were able to consolidate legal and administrative control over the structures of the state; however, the work of transforming these state structures into participatory institutions had only just begun.  The legacy of colonialism had bequeathed societies with a rigid class structure and highly centralised state power.  Thus, by the mid-twentieth century a series of unfinished tasks, with respect to the bourgeois-democratic emancipation of the Third World, still remained at large.  These unfinished tasks gave birth to what John Kautsky calls a “second-wave revolution of modernizers” leading to popular movements, revolutionary coups, insurrections, and mass movements from 1950 to 1980 across the Third World (Katusky 1972, p.197).  The principle contradiction during the second-wave was between the traditional bureaucratic-military oligarchies usually opposed to “any effort to convert the dominant paternalism into a more efficient bureaucracy” and the national bourgeoisie composed of local producing groups that struggled for secular-democratic reforms and a non-aligned position with respect to foreign policy (Cardoso & Galetto, 1979). 

 

Ideological Foundations of the Second Wave

 

Despite individual variations the second-wave of popular nationalist mass mobilisations were bound by certain common ideological tendencies, political, economic, cultural and international guiding assumptions and commonalities.  Before delving into the historical events of the second-wave mobilisations, the ideological foundations of the popular nationalist Afro-Arab-Asian and Latin American solidarity need to be understood. 

 

Commonalities of Pan-African, Pan Arab, Latin-American, and Asian Popular Nationalist Movements of the Mid-Twentieth Century

 

1

 

Ideology

Ideologically these movements were secular and democratic.  These movements were also eager to take steps to better the condition of women in otherwise traditional societies. They often espoused loyalty to “socialism” and the “people”.  However, the principle purpose of the socialist rhetoric was to mobilise popular opinion against the traditional elites.

 

2

 

Politics

These movements opposed monarchical, colonial, bureaucratic, or military regimes and the traditional elites who were in close collaboration with the West.  For the most part, these movements aspired to establish a popular constitutional democratic republic with freedom of press, assembly, organisation and so on.

 

 

3

 

 

Economics

Land reform was viewed as a pre-requisite for a secular-democratic liberal capitalist polity. Monopoly capital, heavy industry, and foreign owned companies were often nationalised and state intervention to build infrastructure and provide welfare was considered a positive step.  On the whole, economic policies pushed towards a democratic capitalism by favouring the national capitalists.

4

International Relations

These regimes formed the non-aligned block whose foreign policy was based on national interest and not ideological commitments to socialism.  These regimes pushed for Third World solidarity in international relations.

 

Since these movements were the product of an era where the bourgeoisie in the West was no longer a revolutionary class, nationalist movements looked towards socialist and working class ideas for inspiration.  Nonetheless, these movements remained firmly within the orbit of bourgeois-democracy.  First, there is no evidence to suggest that these movements wished to “smash the bourgeois state apparatus” in order to construct a dictatorship of the proletariat.  Second, these movements did not challenge private property in and of itself.  The nationalisations undertaken by these movements were not against private property in general but against monopoly capitalism, traditional colonial bureaucracies, large landlords, foreign companies allied to the West.  Third, wherever working class militancy stepped over bourgeois-democratic boundaries, these popular nationalist regimes did not hesitate to crush such radicalism.  From these simple facts, it becomes clear that these nationalist movements did not represent working class communist tendencies but were based on the secular-democratic national-bourgeoisie.

 

This second-wave of popular nationalist mass mobilisation began with the nationalization of the Western oil companies in Iran in 1951 and the swing to populism of that country under Dr. Muhammad Mussadiq supported by the then powerful Tudeh (Communist) Party.  Similarly, in 1952 Bolivia witnessed a powerful land based reform movement and in Argentina the populist Juan Domingo Peron attempted to base his power on the urban and rural poor. In the same fateful year (1952) the “Free Officers Movement” in Egypt led by Gamal Abdel Nasser came to power in a military coup that enjoyed popular support.  In Kenya the contradiction between the reluctance of settler-colonialism to widen the franchise of political power and the dispossession of the Kikuyu tribe from their ancestral lands created the Mau Mau uprising from 1952-56.  Just as the Mau Mau uprising was put down by force, a war of independence against the French colonial authorities burst out in Algeria (1954-1962).  The ideological orientation of this second-wave of nationalist mass mobilisation was captured at the Bandung conference in Indonesia in 1955 where Nehru of India, Sukarno of Indonesia, Nasser of Egypt, and Tito of Yugoslavia met to create the Non-Aligned Movement[1].  The sweeping waves of Afro-Arab-Asian and Latin American solidarity resulted in a series of dramatic changes. Pan-Arab Nasserism resulted in a coup in 1958 that overthrew the government in Baghdad.  In Cuba Fidel Casto and Che Guevara marched to power in 1959 and established he first communist government in the Western hemisphere.  In Tanzania, nearly a decade of independence the first generation independence leader Julius Nyerere himself took up the ‘second great task’ of socialist transformation of the society and introduced an ideology of production under the name of Ujaama.  On the other end of the African continent, Amilcar Kabral in Guinea Bissau fought the Portuguese to a standstill by the end of the 1960s.  In Brazil the heirs of populist leader Getulio Vargas moved to the left in the early in 1960s.  Before their ouster by a military coup the Ba’ath party took power in Syria in 1963.  Even the new communist state of China did not stand outside the tumultuous decade of the 1960s and in 1966 Mao Tse-Tung launched the Great Proletariat Cultural Revolution mobilising thousands of youths in China and across the world.  Revolutionary waves travelled from East to West through the new medium of Television.  Horrific images of the Vietnam War beamed into every household.  When images of the Tet offensive of 1968 revealed the utter barbarity of the war, student protests in opposition to the war erupted across the West.  In the same year a second coup brought the Ba’ath party to power in Iraq.  The Palestinian Liberation Organisation led by Yassir Arafat also took up arms against Israel in the same year (1967-68).  Libya’s ruler, King Idris, was deposed by a handful of ‘socialist’ military officers under the leadership of Colonel Gaddafi in 1969.  In Chile the popularly elected Marxist government of Salvador Allende’s (1970 to 1973) challenged US hegemony in the region.  In 1973 even the otherwise conservative King Faisal of Saudi Arabia decided to take the bold step of raising the price of oil by restricting supply through the OPEC cartel.  The oil cartel resulted in arguably one of the most rapid transfers of wealth from one part of the world to another.  In 1974 the emperor of famine stricken Ethiopia was overthrown by a leftist military coup led by Mingistu.  The same year a similar military coup occurred in Dahomey that changed its name to Benin and declared itself a Peoples Republic.  Madagascar soon followed suit and the new rulers also declared their support for ‘socialism’ in 1975.  In the same year Angola and Mozambique were liberated from Portuguese colonial rule.  In 1979 a similar popular armed revolution named after the patriot Augusto Sezar Sandino overthrew the Samoza family in Nicaragua.  In 1976 white settler rule came to an end after a bitter guerrilla war and four years later Zimbabwe became an independent country (Holland 1985; Hobsbawm 1994).  In April 1978 the monarchy in Afghanistan fell to a coup and the Peoples Democratic Party came to power in Afghanistan.  Till this point all these successful movements were inspired by secular democratic or socialist ideas.  Religious movements, for the most part, had been unable to gain a mass following.  However, in 1979 mass mobilisation on a religious basis destroyed the legitimacy of the Shah of Iran and Ayatullah Khomeni came to power in a Shi’ite inspired mass movement.  Thereafter, movements inspired by religious and traditional ideas became more powerful and visible. 

 

In conclusion, during this entire period (1950-1980) nearly every part of the Third World was in the midst of popular nationalist mass mobilisation and consequently witnessed large-scale mobility on the basis of radical ideologies.  The region of Western Islam, that is the region stretching from Persia (Iran) to Morocco, was in the midst of the sweeping currents of Arab nationalism and Arab socialist doctrines.  Latin America was under the influence of dependency theories that advocated economic and political independence from US hegemony.  East Asia was reeling from the effects of wars in Korea and Indochina, communist ‘conspiracies’, military coups, and Cultural Revolutions.  Pan-African Nationalism provided the ideological underpinnings of the upsurge across Africa against the last vestiges of European settler-colonialism and throughout this period a string of military coups of the left and right spotted the continent of Africa.   However, alongside these waves of popular mobilisation a simultaneous but increasingly influential process of rapprochement and compromise was also underway.

 

Rapprochement and Compromise

 

Even as far back as the 1920s, Lenin spoke of a rapprochement between the bourgeoisie of the oppressed countries and imperialism. Lenin wrote:

 

There has been a certain rapprochement between the bourgeoisie of the exploiting countries and that of the colonies, so that very often -- perhaps even in most cases -- the bourgeoisie of the oppressed countries, while it does support the national movement, is in full accord with the imperialist bourgeoisie, i.e., joins forces with it against all revolutionary movements and revolutionary classes.

 

The second-wave of mobilisations inadvertently created increasingly radical movements because the process of popular mass mobilisation politicised, mobilised, and radicalised classes that had till that point not displayed much historic initiative.  The self-perpetuating dynamics of mass mobilisation fuelled a growing revolt of subaltern classes.  For example, Latin America became a zone of continuous guerrilla wars seeking to emulate the path of the Cuban or Chinese revolutions.  African wars of liberation and populist left-wing military coups had created a series of socialist leaders heading socialist states.  For example, Sekou Toure’ in Guinea, Modibo Krita in Mali, Samora Machel in Mozambique, Augustino Neto in Angola, Mingistu in Ethiopia, Robert Mugabe in Zimbabwe, Amilcar Kabral in Ginnue Bissau looked to ‘scientific socialism’ and ‘soviet power’ as the ideal model.  Similarly, Asia became a hotbed of communist activity.  For example, Noor Mohammed Taraki in Afghanistan, Ho Chi Minh in Vietnam, Kim Il Sung in Korea, and Mao Tse Tung in China, the Naxalites in India, the New Peoples Army in Philippines, the PKI in Indonesia were examples of influential communist movements.  Towards the late 1960s and 1970s nearly every country in the Third World was spotted by leftist revolts of all types and the so-called “Soviet orbit of influence” was growing as a result of the process set in motion by the second-wave of nationalist mobilisation.  These popular nationalist movements were increasingly turning towards Marxism and armed struggle as the solution to the problems of neo-colonialism.

 

The growing fear of radical movements helps explain the change in character of the popular nationalist leaders or parties towards mass mobilisation in the latter part of the 20th century.  As radical movements gained strength, the bourgeoisie in the Third World became increasingly fearful and conservative just like its European counterpart in the 19th century.  The extent of rapprochement by the 1980s can be gauged from the fact that despite the ‘cut-throat’, or at best stringent, neo-liberal Structural Adjustment Policy of the IMF, there was relatively speaking little or no protest from the popular nationalist parties.  Thus, the process of rapprochement and compromise by the 1980s resulted in the capitulation of the popular nationalist parties and the deflation of the second-wave of popular nationalist mass mobilisation.  As the process of rapprochement brought the bourgeoisie in the Third World ideologically and politically closer to the bourgeoisie in the First World, and as the fall of the Soviet Union signalled the destruction of working class organisations built on Marxism, a unique window of opportunity allowed the flourishing of what Samuel Huntington has called The Third Wave of Democracy.  Furthermore, the perceived “capitulation” of the popular nationalist parties compounded with the collapse of the socialist block and the communist movement created an enormous political vacuum in the context of which movements based on traditional, neo-traditional, and religious ideas became increasing visible and sometimes increasingly effective. 

 

In conclusion, the structural transformation of politics in the Third World is the product of an era in which the national-bourgeoisie in the Third World has completely exhausted its revolutionary or anti-imperialist potential and ideologically conservative middle-class forces opposed to both secular working-class movements and secular bourgeois movements have been turning to traditional or neo-traditional ideologies to oppose the hegemony of the West.  The Iranian revolution of 1979 is an archetype of such resistance.  Thus, so-called fundamentalism is built on forces that are opposed to the continuation of the process of bourgeois-democratic emancipation, and therefore, continue to resist the hegemony of the West on the basis of reactionary elements and ideas hoping to turn back the wheel of history.


Figure 2: The Phases of Development of the Bourgeoisie in the Third World

Adolescence                                                      Revolutionary         Conservative

(18th century to 1900)                                                       (WWI – 1979)          (1979 onwards)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 


18th century                                       WWI          WWII           1979              Present

 

If we plot ‘revolutionary potential’ against the passage of time for the bourgeoisie in the Third World (for the purpose of comparing it to figure 1), the shape of the curve would be a narrower inverted U curve.  The figure is meant to demonstrate that the national bourgeoisie in the Third World emerged as a revolutionary force after the First World War and reached the pinnacle of its revolutionary maturity in the period after the Second World War. The Iranian revolution of 1979 marks the death of the revolutionary period of the national-bourgeoisie. Moreover, the curve helps to demonstrate that the bourgeoisie in the Third World travelled the historical distance of the bourgeoisie-democratic transformation in a far shorter period.  In other words, the Third World has experienced a quicker pace of historical development—a notion that helps to explain the existence of highly advanced modes of production side by side with feudal and sometimes pre-feudal modes of production in Third World countries.  The revolutionary era of the bourgeoisie in Europe lasted nearly a century.  In comparison, the bourgeoisie in the Third World emerged quicker owing to the influence of colonial trade and experienced a shorter and more intense revolutionary era lasting a little more than half a century.

In conclusion, the era of Bourgeois Democratic revolutions in the West was completed in the 19th century, in the East it was completed at the end of the 20th century.

 

 

The Incomplete Bourgeois-Democratic Movement in Pakistan

 

In order to better appreciate the dynamics of class struggle in Pakistan, it is necessary to understand the principle features of the body politic of the country.  In other words, it is necessary to grasp both the generalities—that connect developments in Pakistan to Third World politics—and the peculiarities—that distinguish the particular features of Pakistan with respect to the Third World.  In this third and last section, the book will first argue that nationalism in the Muslim community in India and the eventual demand for Pakistan was not the product of an anti-imperialist national-liberation struggle, but instead arose in reaction to the anti-colonial struggle led by the All-India Congress.  Consequently, after partition and independence the state and society of Pakistan had two distinctive features: A highly centralised bureaucratic colonial state and a multinational and diverse society.  Second, the paper will attempt to summarize the politics of Pakistan from independence leading up to the anti-Ayub movement (1947-1968) and show how the contradiction between a centralised state and a multinational society resulted in the creation of Bangladesh in 1971.  Third, the book will critically analyse the anatomy of the Pakistan Peoples Party and argue that the latter should be considered the representative party of the national-bourgeoisie of Pakistan.  The rise and fall of the PPP mirrors the second-wave of popular nationalist mobilisation across the Third World. 

Colonialism and Pakistan

 

In colonial India, the development of trade, commerce, and industry created a nascent capitalist class concentrated around Bombay, Gujarat, Calcutta, and Uttar Pradesh.  This colonial capitalist development, however, proceeded unevenly with respect to different communities.  Furthermore, the reaction of different communities to colonial capitalism was also dissimilar.  Among the Muslims, the ideological and spiritual legacy of the defeat of the Mughal Empire along with the defeat of the broader Islamic empire—that once stretched from Africa to Indonesia—not only destroyed the self-confidence of the community but also made them extremely resistant to all ideas emanating from the West.  In the early period, ideologies of Islamic revivalism were the principle form of resistance to British colonialism and Muslims pinned their hopes on the ideologies of Abdul Wahab or Jamaluddin Afghani.  The failure of these pan-Islamic movements, based as they were on traditional ideologies and historically obsolete classes, to mount a successful challenge to colonialism further deepened the ideological, political, and cultural crisis in the Muslim community.  In conclusion, the development of capitalist relations of production was strongly resisted especially in the early period of colonialism, and consequently, the uneven development of capitalism resulted in a nascent capitalist class that was divided along religious lines.  Naturally these divisions, old prejudices, and discriminatory practices were unreservedly reinforced, reinvented, and exploited by the colonial authorities. 

 

The break with traditional ideologies in the Muslim community came after the defeat in the 1857 “War of Independence”.  The utter defeat of this revolt demoralised and demolished the confidence of the community.  Thereafter, the ideas of Syed Ahmed Khan found an increasing audience.  In this atmosphere of demoralisation, he advocated engaging with the British Empire, learning English, complete cooperation and loyalty to the British, a modern and liberal interpretation of Islam, and open hostility to any revolutionary or national liberation programs.  The colonial authorities, delighted by both his loyalty and liberalism, knighted him for his services to the Empire.  Moreover, in order to further these loyal and liberal teachings and also train young Muslims to enter the colonial administration, the British set up Aligarh University under his directorship.  Aligarh University emerged as the hub of the intellectual life of a new class of increasingly Westernised Muslims who were applying for jobs in the colonial administration, engaging in trade, commerce, business, or professions such as law, teaching, medicine and so on.  Hamza Alavi calls this the “salariat” class—according to Alavi, the salariat is a class that acquires its means of living through a salary from the colonial administration.  In fact, this “salariat” should be considered a nascent bourgeoisie since it was predicated on a mode of life where commodity-exchange was accepted as a universal principle.  This view is also born out by the political developments of this class, specifically, the manner in which the Muslim League[2] came to represent the interests of this nascent bourgeoisie among the Muslims.  In conclusion, the penetration of Western ideas among the Muslims was extremely slow at first; however, with the defeat of movements based on traditional ideologies and the growth of the colonial administration and the economy a small nascent bourgeoisie among the Muslims developed but owing to its size, strength, and ideological orientation it was entirely subservient to the colonial empire. 

 

At the beginning of the 20th century, the anti-colonial movement gained enormous strength and was headed by the All-India Congress in the Sub-continent.  However, the nascent bourgeoisie among the Muslims began to feel increasingly threatened owing to the fact that their mode of existence was tied to the colonial administration.  They feared that with the departure of the British their interests would be threatened by the better organised Congress party and the Hindu sections of the emerging bourgeoisie in India.  Therefore, this class, organised as the Muslim League, began to campaign for constitutional guarantees to safeguard the rights of minorities.  It was in connection with the necessity to safeguard the interests of this class that the idea of a separate state for the Muslims of India was circulated in the 1930s[3] and the name “Pakistan” [4] was coined.  But at that time this idea was only prevalent in the Muslim minority provinces.  For example, Viceroy Wavell remarked, “The Pakistan idea is stronger in the Muslim minority provinces than in the Pakistan provinces…  [The Muslims in these areas] fear marginalisation by the numerically dominant Hindus at the centre of a unitary structure of government advocated by the Congress party” (Noman, 1988, pp. 4).

 

At this point the Muslim League did not command mass support and in the election held in 1936 they were more or less wiped out.  Out of a 109 seats the Muslim League won only 2 from Punjab and 39 from Bengal (Waseem, 1990).  In these Muslim majority provinces regional parties were able to procure the majority of votes and seats.  After this defeat the hitherto, for the most part, secular democratic Muslim League embarked upon a qualitatively different course of action.  First, the Muslim League began to utilise Islam to gain popular support with such slogans as “Islam in danger” and “Pakistan ka matlab kya, La illahah illalallah[5].  Second, the Muslim League began to explicitly campaign for a separate state.  At its 27th conference held in Lahore in March 1940, the party passed what has come to be known as the Pakistan Resolution[6] arguing for a separate state for the Muslims of India. This combination of Islam and modern nationalism appealed not only to the ruling classes of the Muslim majority areas, in the Punjab these slogans appealed to the Muslim peasantry who were indebted to the Hindu merchants, moneylenders, and traders, and in Bengal these slogans appealed to the Muslim tenants who worked under a class of Hindu landlords.  At the popular level the notion of a Muslim or Islamic Pakistan raised expectations of fairness and justice.  The secular Congress or the regionalist parties could offer no comparable program to counter this illusion.  Thus, the contradictions between different economic strata were expressed in communal tones.  In the decade following the defeat of in the 1936 elections, the Muslim League was transformed into a party with popular support and it came to represent not only the interests of the nascent bourgeoisie in Muslim minority provinces but also the landowning interests in Muslim majority provinces (Talbot, 2002).  By 1946 the Muslim League could demonstrate that it commanded electoral strength[7] and street power[8].   Mohammed Ali Jinnah’s political strategy to convince the colonial authorities that the Muslim League should be considered the “sole spokesman” (Jalal, 1985) of the Muslims of India had borne fruit only after an uneasy marriage with landed interests in Muslim majority provinces and Islam.

 

In conclusion, while the All-India Congress expressed the political aspirations of an advanced, highly developed, modern, and secular bourgeoisie that confidently strove towards independence, the Muslim League expressed the political aspirations of a backward, underdeveloped, dependent, and subservient colonial nascent Muslim bourgeoisie in alliance with landowning interests from the Muslim majority provinces.   As a consequence, Pakistan was not the product of a prolonged national-liberation movement but rather the product of legal and constitutional negotiations between the anti-colonial movement led by the All-India Congress on the one hand and the Muslim League and the colonial authorities on the other.  As a result, the manner in which Pakistan was created (including the fact that its Eastern and Western wings were separated by over a 1000 kilometres of Indian territory) gave rise to the enduring opinion, on both sides of the border, but especially in India, that Pakistan was an “artificial state”.  In conclusion, Pakistan, far from being created as a result of a bourgeois democratic liberation movement, was created in reaction to the bourgeois democratic anti-colonial liberation mass movement led by the Congress party.  In a word, the society that became Pakistan in 1947 never experienced a 1789.

 

Independence

 

Independence and partition in 1947 had an enormous and deep impact on the psychology of the newly created Pakistan.  The unexpected horrific forms of communal violence created a bitter divide between the new Pakistan and India.  Approximately 24 million people crossed the border both ways and communal rioting took the lives of some 250,000.  These events had a long lasting effect on the psyche of the Mohajir (migrant) population.  On the other hand, the manner in which the new ruling classes in Pakistan descended upon the property of the emigrating Hindus and Sikhs while refugee camps swarmed and teemed with endless streams of poverty stricken, starving, broken, and often brutalised refugees from India, forcefully demonstrated that the so called ‘land of the pure’ was not the utopia imagined by the Muslim community.  The moment was captured eloquently in Faiz Ahmed Faiz’s poem “Subeh Azadi August 1947”[9].

 

Politically, two notable features stood out with respect to Pakistan after independence.  First, since the creation of the state preceded the creation of a ‘Pakistani nation’, in fact since the creation of Pakistan was based on the two-nation theory that precluded the understanding that the country was composed of multiple nationalities, the state was plagued with problems of national integration from the outset.  A historically unique set of circumstances and an exceptional confluence of interests had brought different communities together to accept the two-nation theory and form a state.  These disparate elements were not, as yet, a united, integrated, and cohesive bourgeoisie.  With the creation of Pakistan the circumstances that brought these diverse interests together no longer existed and the conglomeration of interests fractured.  Thus, the Muslim League splintered and new parties emerged to represent the new alignment of class forces.  The question of national integration posed the most serious threat to Pakistan as a state and society and divided the politics of the country into two camps: those who supported a centralized government and those who supported a federalised government with wide provincial autonomy.

 

Second, since Pakistan was born in reaction to a mass based liberation movement, it inherited an undemocratic, rigid, and non-participatory neo-colonial state structure (Feroz, 1973; Ali, 1996, Ali, 1983).  Colonial politics had conditioned the state structure to protect the interests of the British Empire by ensuring that politics remain within a certain perimeter.  Thus, the principle function of the colonial state was to act as a repressive institute to undermine mass mobilization and participatory democracy.  After independence little or no effort was made to alter the structure of the state to include subaltern classes into the body politics of the country.  In the words of Khalid B. Sayeed, Pakistan inherited a “Viceregal” state (Sayeed, 1980).  Similarly, Hamza Alavi used the term “the condition of the over-developed post-colonial state” (Alavi, 1982). The temptation to utilise this Viceregal overdeveloped state against civil society proved far too great for the new elites to resist (Malik, 1997).  The civil and military bureaucracy continued to intervene in politics in much the same manner as the colonialists before them (Waseem, 1990, pp. 26).  The political system was aptly described by Saleem H. Hashmi as “the government of the secretaries, by the secretaries, and for the secretaries” (Kennedy, 1987, pp. 5).  The state elite viewed political problems as ‘law and order situations’ and attempted to solve these complex issues in a heavy-handed manner and hostility with India was used as a justification for rigid centralisation (Jalal, 1990, pp. 89).  In conclusion, it follows from theoretical consideration and historical analysis that the Viceregal overdeveloped state was the dominant player in the Politics of Pakistan.

 

In sum, the principle contradiction in the early period of Pakistan’s history was between the national movements within Pakistan and the Viceregal state.

 

The most vocal opponents of federalism were the ruling interests of West Pakistan.  The ruling interests of West Pakistan were a combination of the nascent bourgeoisie from Muslim minority provinces in India and the Punjabi landlords.  The nascent bourgeoisie from Bombay and U.P. represented by the old guard of the Muslim League that had settled for the most part in Karachi and Hyderabad.  Owing to their superior education, they became the building blocks of the new financial, industrial, civil, bureaucratic, and state institutions of the country.  With the development of the economy, they developed political and economic ties with the land owning interests of Punjab.  The landlords of Punjab were a powerful political force especially owing to the fact that the bulk of the recruitment for the army occurred in that province.  Furthermore, the Punjab supplied vital agricultural surplus.  These ruling groups were joined by the smaller religiously inspired Jamaat-e-Islami that became the staunchest opponents of provincial federalism.  This conglomeration of interest groups is known as the Establishment in popular political discourse in the country.  The opposition and distrust of the Muslim League towards the regional nationalists had its origins in the independence movement itself.  The establishment took the view that the regional nationalists were not strong supporters of Pakistan and could not be relied to “safeguard the two-nation theory” or the political-ideological borders of Pakistan.

 

On the other hand, the federalists argued for wide provincial autonomy and were a diverse coalition of interests.  The Bengali nationalists were represented mainly by the Awami League (1953) led by Suhawardy and Sheikh Mujib ur Rahman.  The Awami League was backed by a mass based movement with a well-established constituency and was composed of educated personnel that could run the state machinery.  They also possessed the economic strength of the Bengali agricultural economy.  However, they lacked any influence in the armed forces of Pakistan and  also lacked an independent army.  The National Awami Party (1957) led by Maulana Bhashani of Bengal was soon joined in West Pakistan by the Pathan nationalists (led by Ghaffar Khan and his son Wali Khan and Badus Samad Achakzai from the Pukhtun area in Baluchistan), the Baloch nationalists (led by Khair Bakhsh Marri, Ghaus Baksh Bazenjo, Attaullah Mengal, and Akbar Bugti), progressives from the Punjab (led by Mian Iftikhar uddin), and certain elements of the Sindhi nationalists.  The newly formed Communist Party of Pakistan (1948), was forced underground in 1954 when Pakistan moved into the sphere of influence of the United States and became a formal member of the anti-communist military pacts of CENTO (the Central Treaty Organisation included Iraq, Turkey, Iran, and Pakistan) and SEATO (the South East Asian Treaty Organisation included Philippines, Thailand, and Pakistan).  Thereafter the CPP worked in close contact with the regional nationalists in the NAP.  On the whole, these anti-establishment federalists were an anathema to the central government that was trained in the colonial spirit of absolute centralisation.

 

In conclusion, in the early period of Pakistan history one can speak of an establishment composed of the civil military bureaucracy various factions of the Muslim League and the Jamaat e Islami.  And on the other hand one can speak of the forces that were considered anti-establishment composed principally of the regional nationalists and smaller left parties.

 

The Calm Before the Storm 1947 to 1968

 

The exploitative and oppressive nature of the relationship between the central government and the provinces prevented any constitutional agreement between the different interests that now composed Pakistan during the first decade.  According to Omar Noman nearly 70% of the foreign exchange earned by the sale of jute produced in East Pakistan was used to finance industrial development in West Pakistan (Noman, 1988).  Furthermore, this economic exploitation was compounded by national oppression.  For example, the first constitution (proposed in 1956) declared Urdu, spoken by only 3.3% of the population, as the “official” language of the state.  This discrimination towards other languages, especially Bengali which was spoken by 55% of the population, infuriated all the nationalities in Pakistan. 

 

The establishment was unwilling to alter the relationship with the provinces or to make anything other than token concessions.  Since the ruling interests of West Pakistan were unwilling to change the exploitative and oppressive nature of the relationship with the provinces, the regional nationalists were justifiably infuriated by the second-class status accorded to them in the new Pakistan.  As a result, the political forces reached a deadlock that was broken only by brute force with the intervention of the army in 1958.

 

General Ayub Khan undertook an ambitious plan of modernisation.  Pakistan moved firmly into the US sphere of interest and Harvard University trained thinkers such as Gustav Papanek and Samuel Huntington were advising the government’s development policy.  Amongst other measures, the military government created the Basic Democracies[10] system to undermine the basis of regional nationalist politics.  A new highly centralised constitution with a modern Family Laws Ordinance[11] was introduced in 1962. 

 

However, the most significant changes occurred in the sphere of the economy where a strategy of state corporate capitalism was implemented (Noman, 1988).  The government undertook a deliberate program of concentration of capital justified on the basis of the theory of “functional inequality”[12].  There is little doubt that this economic plan increased aggregate growth to phenomenal levels.  Industrialisation proceeded at breakneck speed and Pakistan grew by an average of 6% during the entire decade (Noman, 1988).   Moderate land reforms were undertaken to break-up very large landholdings and Green Revolution technology—including HYV seeds, tractors, tube wells, and small machines (Ali, 1982)—was introduced on a mass level at subsidized rates.  Pakistan’s hitherto sluggish economy burst forward on the path of modern industrial capitalist development.

 

The Anti-Ayub Movement and the New Challengers

 

Ironically the Ayub modernisation did not help to consolidate the establishment but strengthened the hands of the opposition.  The deliberate concentration of capital and the green revolution had the impact of increasing regional and class inequities (Zaidi, 1991).  Modernisation not only created a new class of entrepreneurs but also created an enormous new industrial working class that was becoming more and more organised and radical.  Similarly, in the countryside the green revolution increased landlessness and inequality and the contradictions between the tenants and landed interests began to assume an antagonistic character (Khan, 1981; Ahmed, 1973).  In sum, the economic changes brought about by Ayub Khan had altered the economic base of society and greatly strengthened the classes that desired democratic reforms.  Furthermore, demographically a new generation was coming of age all over Pakistan.  More young people were in touch with the West and the radical changes in international politics were not lost on them.  The contradiction in Pakistan between the obstinate rigidity of the Viceregal system and the growing democratic forces coalesced with the second wave of popular nationalist mass mobilisation across the Third World in the dramatic year of 1968 (Ali, 1973). 

 

Spontaneous student protests in 1968 sparked a nation wide movement against the Ayub dictatorship.  In East Pakistan the people mobilised in millions under the Awami League.  In West Pakistan the astute foreign minister of Pakistan Zulfiqar Ali Bhutto almost as if in anticipation of the coming changes created the Pakistan Peoples Party in 1967 that played a decisive role in the anti-Ayub movement.  The Ayub dictatorship fell under pressure from popular protests just as Samuel Huntington’s famous book lauding Ayub Khan as a modern Roussaeu was hitting the shelves.  Ayub Khan resigned and handed over power to General Yaya Khan who wisely decided to hold the first democratic elections in the history of Pakistan.

 

The anti-Ayub movement and the first democratic election marked a watershed in the political history of the country.  In East Pakistan the Awami League was able to win an astounding 151 out of 153 seats.  In West Pakistan the PPP was able to win 81 out of 131 seats.  In NWFP and Balochistan NAP and JUI were able to form a coalition government at the provincial level (Wilder, 1999).  In accordance with the rules of democracy, the Awami League was entitled to form the central government.  However, the ruling interests of West Pakistan—principally the army and the bureaucracy—prevented the Awami League from doing so because they did not want the latter to alter the exploitative relationship[13] between the eastern and the western wings of Pakistan.  This deadlock resulted in the disintegration of order and civil war between the West Pakistani army and the Bengali nationalist followed.  The India armed forces intervened in 1971 and after a few days of fighting the Pakistani troops capitulated and Bangladesh was born. 

 

In conclusion, the contradiction between the highly centralised state and political forces based on contradictory interests resulted not only in political instability, military dictatorship, but the dismemberment of the country itself.

 

Anatomy of the Pakistan Peoples Party

 

Amidst this chaos, Zulfiqar Ali Bhutto took power on the 20th of December 1971.  In the view of the author the PPP was an archetype of the second-wave of popular nationalist mass mobilisations across the Third World.  In terms of the character of its Pakistani nationalism, its policies towards the different classes in society (specifically the classes composing the establishment, the national-bourgeoisie, and the working class), its position on the state and foreign policy, and, most importantly, its social composition suggest that the PPP represented a national-bourgeoisie opposed to the traditional civil-military establishment.  The rise and fall of the PPP, therefore, is linked to the rise and fall of the national-bourgeoisie as a class across the Third World.

 

Pakistani Nationalism

 

The main figure of the Pakistan Peoples Party, Zulfiqar Ali Bhutto, built his political constituency on the basis of anti-India Pakistani nationalism.  During the 1965 war with India, Bhutto gained popularity by his belligerent stance when he declared in the United Nations that Pakistan would wage a “thousand years war on India”.  He won mass approval especially in the Punjab were anti-India Pakistani nationalism was always high.  Being a man in touch with the times, he skilfully combined this nationalist rhetoric with the slogan of “roti, kaprra, makan” [bread, clothing, shelter] (Aberle).  The 1970 election manifesto of the PPP is a skilful combination of popular nationalism combined with social democratic rhetoric.

 

The PPP’s virulent Pakistani nationalism prevented the party from grasping the significance of regional nationalism in Pakistan.  On this score, Bhutto and the PPP remained Pakistani chauvinists throughout their political history.  For example, during his negotiations with Mujib in 1971 he witnessed the carnage first hand but on his return from Bangladesh he declared, “by the grace of God Pakistan has been saved” (Bhutto, 1971) and covered up the genocide committed by the army in East Pakistan.   In the opinion of Bengali writers, his book The Great Tragedy betrays the thinly concealed “Pakistani chauvinism” for whereas for Bhutto the dismemberment of Pakistan was a tragedy, for the Bengalis, it was liberation.

 

When the PPP was in power, Bhutto continued his nationally chauvinist policies towards the nationalist movement of the Pakhtun and Baloch.  For example, in November-December 1972 the Jam of Las Bela rebelled[14] against the provincial government of NAP-JUI and the provincial government arranged a tribal lashkar[15] to quell the rebellion.  Further, the following month a cash of arms was discovered in the Iraqi embassy and the central government claimed that they were being smuggled to Baluchistan to prepare for an insurgency.  On February 15 1973, Bhutto, claiming that constitutional order had broken down in the province, dismissed the NAP-JUI provincial government and sent four divisions of military (some 80,000 troops)[16] into Balochistan.  The NAP-JUI provincial government in NWFP immediately resigned in protest (Harrison, 1981).  The use of the army to quell this regional nationalist movement shows that Bhutto had learnt little or nothing from the lessons of 1971.

 

On the whole, the position of the PPP with respect to India and with respect to the regional nationalist movements within Pakistan shows that the party’s stance on the national question was in line with a ‘Pakistan based capitalism’.

 

Policies Towards the Establishment

 

In 1972 the PPP nationalised 256 companies including the principle assets of the 22 big families of Pakistan and broke the power of monopoly capital in Pakistan (Shahid ur Rahman Who Owns Pakistan, Hassan, 2000; Burke, 1988; Noman, 1988).  From this simple fact, it becomes clear that the PPP did not represent the interests of the very large capitalists.  At the same time, the PPP upon assuming power undertook a civil service reform in which more than 1,300 of the top bureaucrats were expelled on various charges and a new system of lateral entry into the Civil Services of Pakistan was introduced (Burke, 1988).  This action was hailed at the popular level as a blow against afsarshahi (officer class).  In 1972 the government declared a land ceiling of 150 acres for irrigated and 300 acres for non-irrigated land.  Although land reform only benefited some 75,213 families (Viqar & Amjad, 1984; Zaidi 1997) and did not break the power of large landlords[17]; nonetheless, it was a significant blow to the prestige of landlords because land was taken without compensation and distributed free to landless peasants (Zaidi, 1997; Khan 1981).  In 1977 another land reform was announced, but never implemented owing to Zia’s Marshall Law, declaring a 100 and 200 acres ceiling for irrigated and non-irrigated land respectively (Zaidi, 1997).  Thus, it is clear that the PPP attacked the three principle interests of the neo-colonial state: the bureaucracy, the monopoly capitalists, and the large landlords (Feroz 1973).  From these facts it is not implausible to conclude that the PPP did not represent the aspirations of the establishment.

 

Policies Towards the National-Bourgeoisie

 

The economic policies of the PPP were geared to give special incentives to the small and medium scale urban and rural capitalists.  The Finance Minister Dr. Mubashar Hasan’s engineered a policy of public ownership of large-scale industry and banks and encouraged the development of small and middle scale capitalists (Hasan, 2000).  The government recommended that banks give preferential treatment to small and middle scale capitalists and agriculturalists (Zaidi, 1997) and export promotion schemes and subsidies of various sorts for big capitalists, that were a hallmark of the Ayub’s era, were discontinued. In agriculture the Agricultural Bank of Pakistan was instructed to give credit preference to small and middle peasants. 

 

The only action that appears to go against the interests of the small and middle scale capitalists was the nationalisation of rice husking and flourmills.  The nationalisation of these mills, however, allowed the government to lower the price of basic necessities thus not only boosting voter confidence but also the rate of profit of the entire capitalist class.  Therefore, the losses in direct revenue were small in comparison to the gains for the entire national-bourgeoisie.  Thus, it is not hard to conclude that the nationalisation of these mills did not go against the larger fundamental interests of the small and middle scale capitalists. 

 

Policies Towards the Working Class

 

In the early period, the PPP government removed repressive laws on trade unionism and set labour laws in accordance with ILO standards.  At the same time education was declared universal and free and private schools were nationalised.  Health care was also declared universal and free.  However, contrary to expectations, the PPP did not allocate large sums of money to social services and the bulk of government spending still went to the army (Viqar & Rashid, 1984). 

 

When growing labour militancy resulted in spontaneous factory seizures by workers in 1973 this represented a turning point for the PPP with respect to the labour movement.  The PPP sent in the army and the police to take back the factories in Multan, Karachi, Kot Lakhpat, and Faislabad that workers had taken over.  In Karachi and Multan the army shot and killed many workers which resulted in the estrangement of the labour movement from the PPP. 

 

Furthermore, a strong factional struggle broke out within the PPP between the leftwing of the party and the rightwing of the party.  The leftwing was represented by people like Mubashir Hasan, J.A. Rahim, Miraj Mohammed Khan, Rafi Raza, Sheikh Rasheed.  The rightwing of the party was connected to rural landowning interests and represented by Ghulam Mustafa Khar and Sadiq Querishi (Hasan, 2000, pp. 172-210). Increasingly, the PPP was criticised from the left for purging the radicals from the party and not proceeding with the socialisation of property.  After 1973 the leftwing lost Bhutto’s favour and was gradually purged from the levers of power in the party and state.  Mubashar Hasan’s book The Mirage of Power captures this transformation in detail.  The book shows how independent working class movements, such as the kachi abadi movement (squatter colonies) in Lahore, threatened Bhutto who began to build a new political base among landlords and the army.  By 1977 the PPP relied heavily on large landlords to win the election.  In other words, fear of growing labour militancy transformed the party into an increasingly conservative force demonstrating that the PPP was caught in the classic dilemma of the national-bourgeoisie.

 

 

 

The State

 

The 1973 constitution, presented by the PPP, was the only constitution in the history of the country that was approved by a representative assembly chosen in a universal free and fair election (Raza, 1997).  Asides from injunctions to Islamic Socialism, the constitution upholds private property along with certain provisions for social justice in a federal state.  In sum, the constitution upholds the fundamental principles of a bourgeois-democratic republic (Raza, 1997).

 

The PPP government did not built a ‘peoples army’ on the model of China, as promised in its early manifestoes, but strengthened the existing Pakistan Army.  Bhutto, hoping to create a stronger constituency within the army (Hasan, 2000, pp. xi), not only rearmed the army but also launched the plans to build the so-called ‘Islamic Bomb’.  Till his last days when Bhutto was in his death cell, he continued to appeal to the patriotic sentiments of the armed forces and insisted that the opposition was funded by the US to undermine the plans to build Pakistan’s first atomic bomb (Bhutto, 1977a, 1977b).  In sum, the PPP was not interested in “smashing the bourgeois state” to build a “dictatorship of the proletariat” but in simply strengthened the existing post-colonial state.

 

Foreign Policy

 

Bhutto was a master statesman at the international level and foreign policy was his speciality.  As the foreign minister under Ayub Khan, Bhutto advocated Afro-Arab-Asian and Latin American solidarity for the Third World (Bhutto 1964, 1966, 1969b, 1976).  His book entitled The Myth of Independence is an amalgamation of basic anti-imperialist and dependency theories that were extremely popular among Third World intellectuals in the 1960s (Bhutto, 1968b).  Bhutto advocated friendly relations with the socialist block and especially China.  He termed this foreign policy ‘bilateralism’ which implies a non-aligned policy with respect to the two super-powers (Burke & Ziring 1990; Talbot 1998). 

 

On the basis of building Afro-Arab-Asian and Latin American solidarity Bhutto built links with Islamic countries through the Second Islamic Summit Conference hosted in Lahore in 1974.  The conference brought together diverse elements ranging from conservative leaders such as King Faisal of Saudi Arabia and the Shah of Iran, to radical leaders such as Colonel Gaddaffi of Libya and Yassir Arafat of Palestine.  On the whole, the foreign policy of the PPP was non-aligned and built on the ideological basis of Afro-Arab-Asian and Latin American solidarity. 

 

The Social Composition of the PPP

 

Anwar H. Syed analysing the social composition of the PPP writes,

 

Among the party’s 66 Punjabi MNAs 26 were 40 years of age or younger, one had received only religious education, 20 had passed high or higher secondary school, and 45 held bachelor’s, and in some cases higher, degrees. Their number included six businessmen, three doctors, two engineers, one journalist, 24 lawyers and 30 who listed “agriculture” or “farming” as their occupation. (Syed, 1992, pp. 85, 86)

 

Two of the 20 Sindhi MNAs belonging to the PPP had only had religious education, six had passed high school, and ten held college, or higher, degrees. Seventeen of them were “farmers” and two were lawyers. Four of the Punjabi and two of the Sindhi “farmers” also listed law as their occupation, and one of the Sindhi “farmers” said he was also a businessman.

 

It is noteworthy that he majority of those elected on the PPP ticket from the Punjab were lawyers, professional people, and businessmen rather than landlords. A few of those who called themselves “farmers” 2 were indeed great landlords, but most on the list were probably no more than well-to-do middle-level landowners. By contrast, all but two of the party’s Sindhi MNAs were substantial landlords, and several of them were among the great waderas of Sindh.

 

Thus, in the Punjab the PPP was led by professionals and left leaning capitalists while in Sindh it was based on large land owning interests[18].  In NWFP and Balochistan the PPP was unable to strike deep roots.  On the whole, the PPP derived its electoral mass support from an informal coalition including sections of the urban middle class, the rural gentry, and the urban and rural poor.  Furthermore, several authors have noted that the PPP vote came from those areas that were influenced by the modernization program of Ayub (Wilder, 1999, pp. 7; Burki 1988, Philip Edward Jones, 1979, pp. 498-618; Burki & Baxter, 1975, pp. 173; PERU, 1973, pp. 20-3).  Burke and Baxter write:

 

[T]he PPP polled strongest in those urban and rural tehsils which have been undergoing recent change as measured by the socio-economic indices described above.  In stagnant areas, even though they may be at a higher level of development, the PPP did generally less well and the older Muslim Leagues, the Islamic Parties or independents fared better (Burki & Baxter, 1975, pp. 173-74).

 

This ample evidence supports the view that the Ayub modernisation created and mobilised new political forces that became the base of a new bourgeois class that was represented by the PPP.

 

In conclusion, the historical record of the PPP’s performance in government from 1971 to 1977 shows that the party was built on the ideological basis of a Pakistani nationalism that excluded regional nationalist loyalties.  Nonetheless, the PPP opposed the establishment and the interests of the bureaucracy, monopoly capitalists, and large landlords.  At the same time it was opposed to independent working class movements and in the final analysis favoured small and middle scale capitalists.  The PPP reequipped and strengthen the Pakistan army and did not hesitate to build the so-called ‘Islamic Bomb’. At the international level, Bhutto favoured a non-aligned foreign policy and pursued Afro-Asian-Arab and Latin American solidarity.  The social composition of the PPP composition was a mixture of professional and landed interests that derived mass support from the urban and rural poor especially in areas that experienced rapid modernisation during the 1960s.  On the basis of these factors, it is reasonable to conclude that the PPP represented the national-bourgeoisie in Pakistan.

 

Transformation of the Pakistani National-Bourgeoisie to Conservative Old Age

 

In 1977 Bhutto after having promised a new land reform program felt confident of his popularity and decided to hold an early national election.  Opposition parties quickly united to form the Pakistan National Alliance (PNA)—a coalition of parties whose interests were hurt by the left-leaning policies of the PPP.  When the Election Commission announced a result heavily in favour of the PPP, the PNA charged Bhutto with having rigged the election and began a campaign of street demonstrations.  Bhutto called out the army to restore order.  Powerful interests within the army who were already displeased with the left-leaning policies of the PPP used the deadlock between the PNA and the PPP as justification to declare Marshal Law.  Thus, the PPP was overthrown in 1977 by a coalition of right-wing military generals supported by sections of the middle classes. 

 

General Zia understood that in accordance with the 1973 constitution he had committed a treasonous act.  In order to eliminate his political opponent, Zia put Bhutto on trail in a murder case.  On April 4th 1979, despite the split verdict of the Supreme Court and appeals of clemency from foreign heads of state, Bhutto was executed.  In the same month, the Saur Revolution in Afghanistan broke out and Pakistan became a frontline state in the cold war.  General Zia embarked on a plan of “Islamisation” to prepare the ground for the Mujahideen struggle against the Afghan communists and fight the ideological influence of socialist ideas and the PPP inside Pakistan.

 

After his execution, Bhutto became a martyr in the eyes of the urban and rural and the PPP became a symbol of democratic resistance to Military rule.  As anger against the establishment grew, the Movement for the Restoration of Democracy (MRD) emerged in 1983.  The Sindhi nationalists were the staunchest allies of the PPP whereas the Baloch and Pakhtun nationalists did not join the MRD.  The 1980s also witnessed the creation of a new regional nationalist party in the shape of the Mohajir Quami Mahaz.  The MQM was based on the Urdu speaking Mohajir community in Karachi and Hydrabad and was supported by the establishment in order to undermine the influence of the MRD in the urban industrial centres of Karachi and Hydrabad.  Al-Zulfiqar, led by Bhutto’s son Mir Murtaza Bhutto, was a left split from the PPP and became infatuated with urban guerrilla war and formed links with the Afghan communists.  Nonetheless, the Benazir led opposition through the MRD remained the principle motor of popular mobilisation. 

 

In 1985 Zia held party-less elections to stem the tide of growing criticism to military rule by offering concessions to the democratic movement but this partial restoration of democracy did not adversely affect the popularity of the PPP and Benazir returned to a tumultuous welcome in 1986.  The euphoria created the illusion that Benazir’s return heralded a popular democratic revolution.  This illusion was put to the litmus test when the end of the cold war changed the geo-strategic interests of global actors and the third wave of democracy swept across the world.  Zia was killed in 1988 in an air crash that remains clouded in mystery and elections were held once again in Pakistan.  More or less the same class forces that put together the PNA came together to form the Islami Jamhoori Ittehad (IJI) to oppose the PPP but the latter was able to defeat the IJI and form the central government.

 

On a popular level people expected a return of the radical PPP of the 1970s but Benazir not only accepted the conditions of the army but also of the IMF to implement a process of privatisation and Structural Adjustment Policies (SAP).  The fact that the PPP had succumbed to the policies of the IMF, despite immense popular support, demonstrated that the national-bourgeoisie in Pakistan had reached a level of rapprochement and compromise with the West where it preferred to risk losing mass support but did not wish to risk losing support the of the West.  Naturally, the Structural Adjustment Policies of the IMF were extremely unpopular with the urban and rural poor and consequently the PPP began to loose popularity.  In addition, rumours of corruption became increasingly undeniable tarnishing the image of the party.

 

During this ‘democratic’ decade (1988-1999), both the PPP and the Muslim League came to power twice.  The president dismissed the democratic governments (the PPP in 1993, IJI in 1995, and the PPP again in 1997) under the 8th amendment—a relic of the Zia period that allowed the army to control the parliament.  However, the restoration of democracy failed to satisfy the aspirations of the people and they increasingly became disillusioned with the process of democracy itself.  By 1977 the PPP had lost its former popularity and the Muslim League was able to form the central government with an unprecedented mandate precisely because the PPP voter did not turn out to vote (Wilder, 1999).

 

By the 1980s, as stated earlier, the second-wave of popular nationalist mass mobilisation across the Third World was fading away.  In Pakistan repressive conditions combined with the legacy of Zulfiqar Ali Bhutto allowed the PPP to continue as a motor of mass mobilisation till the 1990s.  However, with the restoration of democracy the class basis and internal degeneration of the PPP could no longer be concealed from the voter.  The decline in the popularity of the PPP has created an enormous political vacuum that no party or movement has, as yet, been able to fill.  In this political vacuum, movements inspired by traditional or neo-traditional ideologies based on religion have become more prominent and visible.  Thus, on the whole, the rise and fall of the PPP runs parallel to the dialectical development of national-bourgeois movements in the Third World that in turn mirror the rise and fall of the bourgeoisie in Europe in the 19th century.

 

 

Conclusion

 

This paper has tried to construct a framework to view the structural transformation of politics in the Third World through the prism of class struggle by arguing that the life-cycle of the bourgeoisie in Europe and the Third World passes through three stages of development: adolescence, revolutionary maturity, and conservative old age.  Admittedly this attempt has only laid down the bare minimum of historical facts and fails to take account of all the intricacies, particularities, twists, turns, and complications in the history of the development of the bourgeoisie.  Nonetheless, this schematic helps to identify and delineate the principle phases of development of history.  Naturally, a deeper and wider appreciation of the complexities of history can help to flesh out the intricacies of the narrative.  The value of the paper, as it stands, lies in the fact that it attempts to string together into a single theoretical whole the dialectical movement of classes and the resulting structural transformation of the bourgeoisie through world history.         The increasing visibility of movements inspired by traditional or neo-traditional ideologies provides testimony to the fact that the secular democratic movements led by the national bourgeoisie in the Third World have recoiled from the tasks of waging an anti-imperialist and democratic struggle. 

 

Therefore, those social forces that expect the emergence of an anti-imperialist struggle on the class basis of the national-bourgeoisie, or those social forces that expect the emergence of a democratic polity on the economic basis of reformed capitalism, or those social forces that expect the creation of a secular and liberal culture on the basis of bourgeois-democracy are essentially harking back to a period of history that has long passed and exhausted its revolutionary potential.  The class that could create a reformed capitalism, the national bourgeoisie, has completely outlived and exhausted its revolutionary, anti-imperialist, or democratic potential.  The national-bourgeoisie has achieved complete rapprochement with imperialism and the status quo.  Those social forces that are still hoping to fight for democracy without challenging capitalism are essentially utopian and are unable to understand the movement of classes or the trends of 20th century history.  History shows that the era of Bourgeois Democratic revolutions in the West was completed in the 19th century, in the East it was completed at the end of the 20th century.

 

The future belongs to a developing working-class movement through out the world.  Only a working class movement based on Marxism-Leninism can lead the struggle against imperialism, reaction, and capitalism.  Only a struggle based on the class foundation of the working-class can continue the struggle for democracy and the liberation of the Third World.  It is even possible that the Third World that entered the world of capitalism last, precisely for that reason, will enter the world of socialism first.


Bibliography

 

Ahmad, Saghir Peasant Classes in Pakistan, in Gough, Kathleen and Sharma, Hari P. (ed.) (1973) Imperialism and Revolution in South Asia, Monthly Review Press, New York and London

Ahmed, Feroz Structure and Contradiction in Pakistan, in Gough, Kathleen and Sharma, Hari P. (ed.) (1973) Imperialism and Revolution in South Asia, Monthly Review Press, New York and London

Ahmed, Iqbal (1988) Pakistan ka Siyasi Nizam, (Trans. The Political Culture of Pakistan), Karachi Press

Ahmed, Viqar; Amjad, Rashid (1984) The Management of Pakistan’s Economy 1947-1982, Oxford University Press

Alavi, Hamza (1982) Capitalism and Colonial production, Croom Helm, London

Albertini, Rudolf  von (1961) Decolonization: the Administration and Future of Colonies, 1919-1960

Ali, Karamat (1982) Pakistan: The Political Economy of Rural Development, Vanguard Publications Ltd.

Ali, Mubarik (1996) Jagirdari aur Jagirdarana Culture (Trans. Feudalism and Feudal Culture), Mashal Press, Pakistan

Ali, Tariq Explosion in South Asia, in Gough, Kathleen and Sharma, Hari P. (ed.) (1973) Imperialism and Revolution in South Asia, Monthly Review Press, New York and London

  (1983) Can Pakistan Survive: the Death of a State Pelican Books

— (2000) On the Abyss, HarperCollins Publishers India

Baxter, Craig (1991) Zia’s Pakistan, West View Press

Belokrenitsky, Vyacheslav, Capitalism in Pakistan: A History of Socioeconomic Development, Patriot Publishers, New Delhi, 1991, p. 99.

Bhutto, Zulfikar Ali (1964) Foreign Policy of Pakistan, Classic

— (1966) Reshaping Foreign Policy, Classic

— a (1968) Political Situation in Pakistan, Classic

— b (1968) The Myth of Independence, Classic

— c (1968) Let the People Judge, Classic

— a (1969) Awakening the People, Classic

— b (1969) Pakistan and the Alliances, Classic

— a (1971) Marching Towards Democracy, Classic

— b (1971) The Great Tragedy, Classic

— (1976) The Third World New Directions, Classic

— a (1977) If I Am Assassinated, Classic

— b (1977) Speeches Delivered Before the UNO and the Security Council, Important Press Conferences, Speeches and Statements vol. 1, 2, 3, 4, Classic

Blood, Peter R. (1994) Area Handbook Series, Pakistan, a Country Study, Federal Research Division Library of Congress

Burki, Shahid Javed (1988) Pakistan Under Bhutto 1971-1977 (second edition), Macmillan

— (1991) Pakistan Under Military: Eleven Years of Zia ul-Haq Westview Press.

— (1999) Pakistan: Fifty Years of Nationhood, (third edition) Westview

      Ziring, Lawrence (1990) Pakistan’s Foreign Policy, Oxford University Press

      (1975) Craig Baxter, ‘Socio-Economic Indicators of the Peoples Party Vote in the Punjab: A Study at the Tehsil Level” in W.H. Wriggins, ed., Pakistan in Transition, Islamabad

Cardoso, Fernando Henrique, and Enzo Faletto (1979) Dependency and Development in Latin America Berkeley: University of California Press

Davidson, Basil (1980) Africa (8 part documentary series on Africa).

Facts about Pakistan, Karachi Press, 1985

Faiz Ahmed Faiz (1984) Nuskha e hai wafa, Maktabai Karwan, Lahore (Urdu)

Gardezi, Hassan N. Neo-colonial Alliances and the Crises of Pakistan, in Gough, Kathleen and Sharma, Hari P. (ed.) (1973) Imperialism and Revolution in South Asia, Monthly Review Press, New York and London

Halliday, Fred (1983) The Making of the Second Cold War, London

Halperin, Sandra (1997) In the Mirror of the Third World: Capitalist Development in the Third World Cornell University Press

Harrison, Selig S. (1981) In Afghanistan’s Shadow: Baluch Nationalism and Soviet Temptations, Carnegie Endowment for International Peace

Harriss, John Capitalism and Peasant Production: The Green Revolution in India, in Shanin, Theodor (1971) Peasants and Peasant Societies Basil Blackwell.

Hasan, Mubashar (2000) The Mirage of Power: An Inquiry Into the Bhutto Years 1971-1977, Oxford Univeristy Press

Hobsbawm, Eric (1962) The Age of Revolution, London

  (1975) The Age of Capital, London

— (1987) The Age of Empire, London

— (1987) The Age of Extremes, London

Holland, R.F. (1985) European Decolonisation 1918-1981, Basindstoke

Human Development Report [1995 and 1993] Published for the United Nations Development Program (UNDP), New York, Oxford, Oxford University Press, [1995 and 1993].

Jalal, Aisha (1985) The Sole Spokesman: Jinnah, the Muslim League and the demand for Pakistan Cambridge University Press

— (1990) The State of Martial Rule Cambridge University Press

Jansen, Godfrey. H. (1979) Militant Islam, Pan Books London and Sydney

Jones, Philip Edward (1979) The Pakistan Peoples Party: Social Group response and Party Development in an Era of Mass Participation unpublished Pg.D. dissertation

Kautsky, John (1972) Political Consequences of Modernization, New York

Kedourie, Elie (1970) Nationalism in Asia and Africa, New York

Kennedy, Charles H. (1987) Bureaucracy in Pakistan, Karachi, New York, Oxford University Press

Khan, Mahmood Hasan (1981) Underdevelopment and Agrarian Structure in Pakistan, Westview Press

Kurian, George Thomas (1978) Encyclopedia of the Third World, Facts on File, New York, NY, Oxford, England

Lenin, V.I. (1977) The Historic Destiny of the Doctrine of Karl Marx,

  Imperialism the Highest Stage of Capitalism,

  Backward Europe and Advanced Asia,

  The Revolution in China,

  On the National and Colonial Question, all in Selected Works, Progress Publishers Moscow

Mahmood, Moazam ‘The Pattern of Adoption of Green Revolution Technology and its Effect on Landholdings in the Punjab’, in Ali, Karamat (1982) Pakistan: The Political Economy of Rural Development Vanguard Publications Ltd.

Malik, Iftikhar H. (1997) State and Civil Society in Pakistan, Macmillan

Marx, Karl & Engels, Fredrick (1983) The Portable Karl Marx edited by Eugene Kamenka, Ludwig Feuerbach, The Manifesto of the Communist Party, German Ideology Penguin Books

Moore, Barrington (1966) Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy, Boston: Beacon.

Mushtaq, Ahmed (1970) Government and Politics of Pakistan, Space Publishers

Noman, Omar (1988) The Political Economy of Pakistan 1947-85, KPI London and New York

Pakistan Peoples Party Election and Party Manifesto (1970 - 1968 - 1977) from www.ppp.org

(PERU) Pakistan Economic Research Unite (1973)‘The General Elections 1970: an Analysis of Socioeconomic Trends in West Pakistan, Karachi

Raza, Rafi (1997), Zulfiqar Ali Bhutto 1967-1977, Oxford University Press

Rizvi, Hasan Askari (1973) Pakistan Peoples Party: the First Phase 1967-71 Progressive Publishers

Sayeed, Khalid B. (1968) Pakistan the Formative Phase, Oxford University Press

  (1980) Politics in Pakistan, The Nature and Direction of Change, Praeger Special Studies

Seal, Anil (1968) The Emergence of Indian Nationalism, Cambridge

Syed, Anwar H. (1992) The Discourse and Politics of Zulifiqar Ali Bhutto, Macmillan

Talbot, Ian (1998) Pakistan: A Modern History, Hurst & Company, London

  (2002) Khizr Tiwana: the Punjab Unionist Party and the Partition of India, Oxford University Press

Waseem, Mohammed (1990) Politics and the State in Pakistan Oxford University Press

Wilder, Andrew (1999) The Pakistani Voter: Electoral Behaviour in the Punjab, Oxford University Press

Wolf, E. (1982) Europe and the Peoples Without History, Berkeley 1982.

Wolpert, Stanley (1984) Jinnah of Pakistan, Oxford University Press

Wolpert, Stanley (1993) Zulfi Bhutto of Pakistan, Oxford University Press

Zaidi, Akbar S. (1991) Regional Imbalances and the National Question

  (1997) Issues in the Pakistan Economy Oxford University Press

 

[1] In fact, the use of the term “Third World” became increasingly popular after this very conference.  The term simultaneously implied a non-aligned and underdeveloped world and provided the theoretical and organisational underpinnings to motivate other Third World states become non-aligned with respect to the rivalry between the super-powers. 

[2] The original membership qualifications of the Muslim League included the ability of “reading and writing with facility” and an income of not less than Rs. 500 a year (S. Shamsul-Hassan (ed) Plain Mr. Jinnah, Karachi, 1976 pp. 299-300.  50 out of the 33 members of the Simla deputation and only 8 out of the additional 35 members of the Muslim League nominated at its 1906 session at Karachi belonged to the future Pakistan areas (ibid).

[3] The poet and philosopher Mohammed Iqbal had given expression to the idea of a separate state in the 1930s

[4] Chaudhry Rehmat Ali coined the term “Pakistan” in 1933.  The word meaning ‘land of the pure’ was composed of letters from the different regions of what was to become Pakistan in 1947 (P for Punjab, A for Afghania (NWFP), K for Kashmir, S for Sindh, TAN for Baluchistan).  Ironically Bengal was absent from this name.

[5] Translation “What is the meaning of Pakistan, There is no God but Allah” (the last phrase is the central kalima of the Islamic faith. 

[6] At the time it was known simply as the Lahore Resolution and the name Pakistan was not mentioned.

[7] The election of 1946 demonstrated that the Muslim League commanded the majority of votes in Muslim majority provinces.

[8] The Direct Action Day was meant to demonstrate the street power of the Muslim League

[9] Yeh dagh dagh ujala, yeh shab gazeedah sahar, woh intezar tha jis ka, yeh woh sahar to nahin

[10] The Basic Democracy system divided into 80,000 geographical units with an average electorate of 1,000 each.  These units were responsible for electing a ‘basic democrat’ who would then elect a President.  On this basis General Ayub Khan was elected President by a simple ‘yes’ or ‘no’ answer to the question: “Have you confidence in President Ayub Khan?”

[11] The religious parties, especially the Jamaat e Islami, opposed this constitution as “unIslamic”.  Thus, the basis of the opposition of Maulana Maududi to the modernisation by Ayub Khan was essentially reactionary.

[12] The theory argued that the concentration of capital was necessary in order to boost investments and savings.  Twenty-two families were handpicked and given special tax creaks, subsidies, and other favourable incentives to lead this industrial revolution.  It was thought that high savings and investments would boost economic growth the benefits of which would eventually trickle down to the people. 

[13] In the view of the author, Mujib’s six-point program was aimed precisely at creating a relationship of equality between the two wings of Pakistan. 

[14] The Baloch nationalists claim that the rebellion was fostered by the secret support of the central government and Prime Minister Bhutto.

[15] The principle leaders who put together this lashkar and later headed the militant section of the Baloch nationalist movement were Khair Buksh Mari, Ataullah Mengal, and Ghaus Baksh Bazenjo.  The non-militant section of the Baloch nationalism movement was headed by Akbar Bugti.  They claim that the Baloch Constabulary refused to intervene to put down the rebellion, thus, their hand was forced.

[16] The result of the use of the army to quell the Baloch nationalists was that the establishment gained confidence to intervene in politics.  However, this intervention was still in the periphery of the country and a similar justification would be necessary to intervene in the major cities of the country.  That opportunity came much later with the Pakistan National Alliance (PNA).

[17] Some 308,390 acres were redistributed from 1972-78.  In other words, only 1 percent of the landless tenants and small owners benefited from the land reform

[18] It must be added that these landowning interests of Sindh were integrated into the cotton cash cropping economy. 

 

 
Send mail to cmkp-owner@yahoogroups.com.
Last modified: March 27, 2004
1