Friday, September 21, 2001
Dr. Schwab spoke briefly about the ideas of statutory and economic tax incidence and will get to something called tax shifting. First let's review the definitions we got in class:
Take Dr. Schwab's example from class. Suppose gas costs $1. Now suppose a law is passed to tax each gallon of gas $0.30 when it is sold, to be paid by gas station owners. If the gas station owners can't raise the price, then they bear the full burden of the tax. Instead of getting $1 for each gallon of gas they sell, the gas station owner effectively gets $0.70 per gallon ($1 price minus the $0.30 paid in tax). Now suppose the gas station owners can raise the price to $1.30. Who bears the burden of the tax? The consumers, because for each gallon of gas the station owners are receiving $1 ($1.30 price minus the $0.30 paid in tax).
Suppose we look at the market for food. This table of data is identical to the one from the purple book of Dr. Schwab's Powerpoint Slides on page 2 of Chapter 6. The first thing we will do is duplicate what was done in lecture. Suppliers are willing to sell 24 units of food when they receive $13 per unit. When there is no tax on suppliers, this means they are willing to sell 24 units when the price paid by demanders is $13 per unit. When there is no tax, the price paid by demanders and the revenue received by suppliers are identical. Similarly, Suppliers are willing to sell 7 units of food when they receive $7 per unit of food. When there is no tax on suppliers, this means they are willing to sell 7 units of food when demanders pay a price of $7 per unit. This is the no-tax equilibrium: P=7, Q=12. Suppose government passes a $2 per unit tax on food that is paid by the suppliers of food. These guys would like to try and dodge having to pay the tax. The tax creates a gap between the price paid by demanders and the revenue received by suppliers. This is because the demanders pay the market price, but government steps in and takes the tax burden out of the suppliers' revenue. After the tax is imposed on sellers, what happens to supplier willingness to sell? Let's look at the price $13 paid by demanders. When there was no tax, the sellers received the full $13 per unit and were willing to sell 24 units of food. However, now the government is taking $2 per sale out of the price paid by demanders. Thus, suppliers only end up with $11 of the $13 paid by demanders. How many units of food are producers willing to sell when they only receive $11? They will only sell 20 units of food when they end up with $11. So at P=13, suppliers are willing to sell less. |
|
|
What happens is that at every price paid by demanders, suppliers are willing to sell less. This is the definition of a leftward shift of the supply curve. Of course, demand stayed the same, so now we have the same amount of demanders fighting over fewer units supplied at each price. What's the new equilibrium after the tax gets passed? It occurs at the intersection of the unchanged demand curve and the new leftward shifted post-tax supply curve. When we look at the table, this happens at P=8 and Q=10. |
Now the 64 dollar question is: where did the economic incidence of the tax fall? Who actually bore the burden of the tax? In this food example, the equilibrium changed from P=7, Q=12 to P=8, Q=10. Two things happened here:
Suppose government passes a $2 per unit tax on food that is paid by the demanders of food. Just like the suppliers, demanders would like to dodge having to pay this tax. The most obvious thing that will happen is that demanders will shift to untaxed substitutes. In the case of food, that kind of doesn't make sense. A story we could tell here is that maybe people were overeating before the tax and after the tax cut down to only eating enough to survive. After the tax is imposed on demanders, what happens to demanders' willingness to buy food? Let's look at the price $11 paid by demanders. When there was no tax, the demanders paid just the $11 per unit price and were willing to buy 4 units of food. However, now the government is adding additional $2 tax to the price paid by demanders. Thus, when price is $11, the demanders must really pay $13 to cover the price and the tax charge. How many units of food are demanders willing to buy when they must pay $13? They will only buy 1 unit of food when they must pay $13. So at P=11, demanders are willing to buy less. |
|
|
What happens is that at every price paid by demanders, demanders are willing to buy less. This is the definition of a leftward shift of the demand curve. Of course, supply stayed the same, so now we have the fewer demanders fighting over the same number of units supplied at each price. What's the new equilibrium after the tax gets passed? It occurs at the intersection of the unchanged supply curve and the new leftward shifted post-tax demand curve. When we look at the table, this happens at P=6 and Q=10. |
Again, the 64 dollar question is: where did the economic incidence of the tax fall? Who actually bore the burden of the tax? In this second food example, the equilibrium changed from P=7, Q=12 to P=6, Q=10. Two things happened here:
Okay, so the chain of events we have so far is this: