Revised
draft
June
29, 2001
Introduction
Papua New Guinea
(PNG) celebrated its first 25 years of independence from Australia on 15th
September 2000. There were those who believed there was little to celebrate,
as the government led by Sir Mekere Morauta struggled to restore governance
after the near collapse of the main institutions of public life during
the premiership of Bill Skate (July 1997 to July 1999). A World Bank report
(2000b) had commented early in 2000 that “the country has experienced
an almost complete failure of governance”, while a leading business journal
described the country as “the business environment from hell, [with] interest
rates at 23 per cent, inflation 14 per cent, unemployment 36 per cent,
corruption endemic, only a third of children at primary school, only half
the population literate…[and] top of the world in violent crime” (Callick,
2000).
This paper’s
update of APEL’s previous review of the PNG economy (Duncan and Temu 1995)
offers a more balanced account of what are nevertheless disappointing outcomes.
The paper concludes thatsuccessive
governments’ failure to address land reform could well explain why their
fiscal and monetary policies have limited the second round, “multiplier”,
creation of wealth that should have resulted from the country’s strong
export performance.[1]
Tim
Curtin was formerly a consultant in PNG’s Treasury from1988 to 1999, and
is currently a special adviser to the PNG Government in its negotiations
with Bougainville.
Within three years of the closure of the Panguna copper mine in 1989, which had been PNG’s largest single exporter, new gold mines at Misima, Porgera, and the oilfields around Lake Kutubu (in Milne Bay, Enga, and Southern Highlands respectively) more than replaced its contribution, together with expanded copper output from Ok Tedi (Western Province) and since 1997, the Lihir gold mine (in New Ireland). Total exports rose from US$1.5 billion in 1988, the last full year of production at Panguna, to US$2 billion in 2000, despite the large fall in the price of gold since 1997, that having been the country’s most valuable export commodity as recently as 1995.
Prospects for the mineral sector for the next 10 years are of steady decline, as old mines close (Misima in 2001, Porgera, Ok Tedi) and output from the oil fields drops from the peak of 46 million barrels in 1994 to less than 10 million in 2010. Land disputes threaten to delay indefinitely Chevron’s project to export natural gas to Queensland from PNG’s large unexploited gas reserves.
Exports of US$2 billion a year amount to US$435 per head of the population, and account for half of current GNP per head. Various observers have pointed out that this export performance has not flowed through to the rest of the economy, describing the mineral project areas as mere enclaves. There may be some justice in this comment, not least because all the mineral areas have been distant from the main population centers and from each other, so there has been no scope for shared infrastructure such as power and transport. However there is no doubt that Port Moresby has benefited as a service centre for legal and financial services to the mineral industry, although to a declining extent since the capital’s law and order problems have led to an exodus of technical and administrative staff to Cairns and Brisbane (see Levantis 2000, 2001b for fuller discussions of the impact of law and order on business development in Papua New Guinea).[2]
Such factors
may explain the discrepancy between wage employment in 1990 reported by
the 1990 Census and the level of employment implied by applying the BPNG
index to enumerated private sector employment in 1982. The BPNG index implies
the latter to have been 139,500 in 1990, well below the 185,000 indicated
by the Census estimate for total wage employment of 240,763 and the known
level of public sector employment of 55,452 (McGavin 1997, table 2.3).
Despite PNG’s
apparently poor job creation record, Fig. 1 shows how some sectors have
grown rapidly over the last 11 years, notably mining (52.7 per cent to
June 2000), manufacturing (33.4), and finance (36, down from 50 per cent
in 1999), and community services (mainly due to a doubling in the number
of teachers). These increases may be partly a response to the changes in
the policy environment, but the growth of the services sectors is in line
with similar trends worldwide.
The evident
slow growth of wage employment is reflected in the remarkable decline in
the share of compensation of employees in GDP, from 38.6 per cent in 1984
to 22.28 per cent in 1998 (Fig.4), one of the lowest shares in any country
worldwide. That is naturally matched by the corresponding large increase
in the share of gross operating surplus in GDP, from 44 per cent in 1984
to 62 per cent in 1998, with part of this increase due to minor falls in
the shares of depreciation and net indirect taxes. Much of the increased
share of profits is no doubt accounted for by the mineral sector, especially
oil after the Kutubu project began production in 1992. But this enormous
rise in the share of profits in GDP has not been matched by a rising contribution
to government revenue.
Indeed, contrary
to the expectation of Duncan and Temu that the mineral sector, which provided
20 per cent of government revenue in 1989, could produce more than 35 per
cent by 1999 (p.49), in the event it produced only 12 and 16 per cent of
total non-aid revenue in 1999 and 2000 respectively (see Table 3). Although
non-mining companies paid nearly as much in corporate taxes as the mineral
companies in 1999, the total contribution of company taxation to government
revenue was 24 per cent, less than half the profits share of GDP. Evidently
the growth of profits has not expanded the narrow tax base noted by Duncan
and Temu (p.41), in part because of the low company tax rate of 25 per
cent (except for mining 35 per cent until 2001 and petroleum 50 per cent).
Social indicators
Despite the
slow growth of the monetary economy implied by the wage employment index,
and the perverse falling contribution of profits to general taxation, there
has been continuation of the “significant progress in social development”
reported by Duncan and Temu (p.37). Although infant mortality remains too
high for comfort, life expectancy has improved (see Table 1). Duncan and
Temu noted (Table 1) that in 1995 PNG’s health and education indicators
did not compare well with performance in East Asia and the World Bank’s
lower middle-income countries – but the latter are hardly valid comparators
with a country whose nominal exchange rate has been consistently over-valued,
exaggerating its GDP in US dollar terms, and whose colonial rulers uniquely
provided no public education or health services for its indigenous population
before 1946. Table 1 here compares PNG with its peers in the low-income
group of countries.
The 1990 Census
showed that 232,000 children aged 10-14 out of 436,645 in that age-group
were at school, or 53 per cent. On paper this had improved to at least
87 per cent in 1998, for then there were 668,000 children enrolled in elementary
and primary schools, while the 1990 Census showed that there were then
763,873 in the 0-6 age-group who would have been aged 8-14 in 1998 (had
none died). Allowing for mortality at about one per cent p.a. reduces the
extant age-group in 1998 to 704,000, implying about 95 per cent enrolment
of that age-group in 1998, an as yet unnoticed but considerable achievement,
and also an indication that the large budget allocations to education since
the beginning of the 1990s are having an impact – education accounted for
as much as 17 per cent of the national budget in 1998, very high by world
standards (World Bank, 1998). However drop-outs remain a problem, especially
when parents cannot afford fees, rising from over K100 per child at the
primary level to K300 at secondary.
The 1990 Census
also showed that only about half the population aged over 10 was receiving
or had obtained some schooling, and was therefore potentially literate.
But the rapid growth of enrolments since 1990, and the likely demise of
many of the older illiterate members of the population, explains the reduction
in illiteracy to 27 per cent (Table 1) - still high, but significantly
less than Callick’s 50 per cent.
Comparison of
the 1980 and 1990 Census data on the educational status of employed workers
showed that it was those with at last some post-primary schooling that
much more easily found jobs than those with only primary schooling, who
fared little better than those with none (Curtin 1996). This finding was
supported by data in a World Bank study (Ahuja 1998) showing that the majority
of the poor in five S.E. Asian countries including PNG were those with
only primary schooling, whilst hardly any of those with at least some secondary
schooling were to be found amongst the poor. Moreover post-primary education
has demonstrably been more effective than primary in raising awareness
of health (e.g. Aids) and maternal care issues in PNG’s female population
(Curtin and Nelson 1999).
The difficulties
created by the lack of certificated land title in both the mining and forestry
sectors have been well described by the contributors to Toft (1997) and
Larmour (1997). For example, Filer (1997) and Duncan and Duncan (1997)
show how compensation paid for supposed losses incurred by putative landowners
in mining areas have progressed to become in effect land rentals unrelated
to the losses. Had there been formal tenure at the outset, sales or rental
agreements could have been negotiated. In their absence, “compensation”
claims become an on-going saga that is no doubt a powerful deterrent to
investors in all but the most lucrative prospects. But the main issue is
the inability of so-called landowners to mobilise bank credit in the absence
of certificated title. A telling example is the decision by the landowners
in the Porgera mining area to acquire real estate in the form of two tower
blocks in Port Moresby, where leasehold title is available, rather than
investing more in their home areas.
Jones and McGavin (2000) described
how difficult it is even for those Papua New Guineans who do seek to register
their land ownership to surmount the bureaucratic obstacles and sheer inertia
that stand in their way. Their study calls to mind the similar work by
de Soto (2000) in Peru, Haiti, and Egypt, where a normal lifetime may well
not be long enough to achieve registration of title. Yet as de Soto suggests,
the land rights of the peasantry as much in a country like PNG as elsewhere
are worth much more – if they could only be mobilised as collateral - than
the total aid receipts the country has ever received. A first step would
be to adopt the proposal by Trebilcock and Knetsch (1981) for establishment
of an autonomous Land Management Agency.
The general
elections in 1997 continued the patterns whereby only a small minority
of MPs was elected with more than 50 per cent of votes cast; most seats
were contested by large numbers of candidates, and many MPs won with as
little as 15 per cent of the votes. Sir Julius Chan was the first incumbent
prime minister to lose his seat at an election, but his party continued
to be in government until late in 2000. His successor Bill Skate was only
the second prime minister to take office after a general election, and
in 1999 became the fifth to lose office on the floor of Parliament rather
than after an election, when most of his supporters deserted to join the
grouping put together by his Minister of Planning, Sir Mekere Morauta.
Against this
background of a virtual absence of party-based politics, the Morauta government
succeeded in November 2000 in amending the Constitution with the Integrity
of Political Parties Act. This Act seeks to limit the freedom of MPs to
change parties and to leave/join the government/opposition groups in Parliament.
It also provides for a degree of state funding of parties, and for party
office-holders not to be eligible for top-level employment in statutory
and other public bodies. But the most significant clauses in the Act are
those providing that after future elections it will be the leader of the
largest party who becomes prime minister, unlike the present system whereby
the prime minister is elected on the floor of the house. The new system
would rule out Bill Skate, who became prime minister in 1997 even though
his party won only 6 seats.
Duncan and Temu
identified a number of areas where the provincial government system that
PNG adopted in 1977 had weaknesses (p.39).A
major reform of the system was enacted in 1995. The new system abolished
provincial parliaments with their own elected governments, and replaced
them with assemblies consisting of ex officio members including the nationally
elected MPs in each respective province, and with premiers replaced by
governors, normally each province’s “regional” MP, elected by the province
as a whole (all other MPs are elected on a constituency basis).
The limited
financial autonomy of the old system whereby certain provinces had their
own revenue raising powers and could use them to fund their functions independently
of the central government was also modified in 1995. The main source of
funding of provincial governments (and local councils) is now a range of
block grants from the national government, apart from a share (30 per cent)
of the national value added tax introduced in 1999. Centralisation of funding
and decentralisation of spending led to a notable loss of expenditure control,
exemplified by the collapse of rural health services.
The fundamental
defect of the reduced fiscal autonomy of provincial governments since 1995
is the separation of taxing and spending powers. Whilst common enough in
federations like Australia, the experience in PNG before 1995 was that
the 8 provinces granted power to levy taxes managed their spending functions
better than the 11 that were wholly financed by the central government
(Axline 1986).
The establishment
of provincial governments in 1977 had been a response to moves to secession
from PNG by the North Solomons Province, now known as Bougainville. Opposition
to the continued operation of the copper mine at Panguna was combined with
a new thrust for secession in 1989. The national government’s forces were
expelled and there was an internal civil war. Negotiations to reintegrate
Bougainville into PNG with a high degree of political and financial autonomy
have been in progress since 1997, with particular emphasis on allowing
the autonomous government to levy its own personal income and excise taxes
and to retain a proportion of national taxes (company, customs, VAT) collected
in Bougainville to enable it to be fiscally self-supporting. It is possible
that the final model if adopted could be extended in time to the other
18 provinces, completing the move to a federal system that was partially
contemplated in 1977 but reversed in 1995.
Economic Developments since
1995
Duncan and Temu
described how because of its dependence on primary commodity exports, PNG
experiences marked boom-bust cycles with strong GDP growth in some years
followed in other years by nearly as large falls (p.36).That
pattern has continued since 1995, with first a period of falling world
oil prices until late in 1999, and then a rapid surge in 2000 and 2001
to the highest recorded levels since PNG’s oil production began in 1992.
The world gold price also fell markedly after 1996 and at time of writing
remains $120 an ounce below the US$380 level on which the feasibility of
the Lihir gold mine was predicated in 1995.
The East Asian
financial crisis in 1997 led to a sharp fall in prices of logs and palm
oil, PNG’s most valuable non-mineral exports in 1994. In addition PNG experienced
a devastating drought in 1997 that ravaged food and cash crop production
in the highlands and other areas as well as halting production of copper
and gold at Ok Tedi and Porgera. The combination of falling prices of logs,
palm oil, gold, and oil, and the drought-induced falls in production of
these commodities in 1997 and 1998 certainly created a classic exogenous-shock
bust, initiating a recession in 1998 from which as yet there are few signs
of recovery, despite higher crude oil prices since 1999.
Duncan and Temu
commented that although PNG had applied “generally sensible policies” to
the minerals sector, and that “its macroeconomic policy adjustments work
extremely well by comparison to [those of] most other developing countries”
facing boom and bust resource exports, “the rest of the economy presents
a mostly depressing picture within a policy framework that seems to include
most of the worst kinds of rules and regulations” (p.36). These judgments
largely remain valid, although the macroeconomic response to the drought-induced
mineral and coffee exports slump in 1997 was poorly handled. There has
been some progress in dismantling a few price controls and restrictions
on foreign investment, but there is no justification for the remaining
controls. The use of price control to delay changes in energy prices and
airfares to reflect the near tripling of fuel costs in 1999-2000 has been
almost as disastrous for the electricity commission and airlines in PNG
as for the power utilities in California in 2001.
For most of
the period covered by Duncan and Temu, PNG maintained a fixed exchange
rate, with administered appreciations in the later 1970s followed by two
limited realignments in 1982 and 1990. In August 1994 the Kina was still
nominally worth more in terms of the Australian dollar than at independence
in 1975. Duncan and Temu (p.44) attributed the enforced devaluation in
September 1994 to fiscal laxity over the previous decade, but capital flows
had also been adversely affected – in both directions - by the then Government’s
compulsory purchase of an extra 15 per cent share in the Porgera Gold Mine
Joint Venture in 1993 and its threats to take similar action with the new
Lihir gold mine in 1994. These threats delayed the startup of construction
of that mine until late 1995 – and did nothing to sustain overseas investors’
confidence in PNG.
Garnaut (1995)
concluded that the objectives of the hard (fixed) Kina regime had been
achieved into the 1990s, despite some fiscal relaxation after 1985, in
terms of currency convertibility, low inflation, and low interest rates.
Equally there is no doubt that the floating of the Kina has since 1994
been associated with high inflation and high interest rates. These have
resulted partly from the actual increase in currency convertibility that
followed on the floating of the Kina and facilitated capital outflows.
The authorities’ administered increases in interest rates were aimed at
stemming the capital outflows that had led to the declines in the nominal
exchange rate, but those declines raised import prices and the CPI, both
accommodated by the enlarged money supply arising from the increase in
the Kina value of exports, and leading to further depreciation of the Kina,
yet higher Kina values of exports and imports, and a new round of increases
in the money supply and the CPI. The inflationary spiral depicted here
in Fig. 6 is typical of countries like Indonesia that since 1997 have failed
to establish price stability after floating their currencies – and explains
the faster depreciation of PNG’s nominal than its real exchange rate (Fig.5).
Garnaut (1983
and 1995) emphasised what he saw as the difficulties created for macroeconomic
policy by the indexation of minimum wages after 1975. Indexation ended
in 1992, so wage inflation cannot be blamed for the failure to achieve
macroeconomic stability since then. On the contrary, wages have not merely
failed to keep pace with prices since 1992, but, for all except the top
quintile of employees, have fallen far behind (see Table 2 for average
nominal and real wages by quintiles). This failure of nominal wages to
keep pace with prices is consistent with the fall in the share of employee
compensation in GDP noted above.
Levantis (2000)
argues that de-indexation and the reduction in the urban minimum wage to
parity with the rural did lead to increases in wage employment, despite
the official index showing virtually no growth in private sector employment
since 1989. An alternative explanation for the apparent correlations of
wage indexation with both rising employment between 1975 and 1992, and
of de-indexation with stagnant employment since 1992 could be that indexation’s
macro-economic effect was to protect the purchasing power that has collapsed
since 1993.
All data on
actual wages received by the labour force shows that except in the rural
plantation sector, the majority of even the lowest paid workers have always,
both before and after de-indexation, earned more than the statutory minimum
wage. Thus Garnaut (with Curtain and Wright, 1977) showed how as early
as the mid-1970s, urban employment in PNG was dominated by those with at
least some education. This pattern was confirmed by McGavin’s data (1988)
for urban employment in the mid-1980s, showing nil employees earning only
the minimum wage, and again by Levantis (2000, p.81), who showed that unskilled
employment was concentrated in the rural sector. Similarly, when the urban
minimum wage was reduced to the rural in 1992, most urban employers continued
to pay much more than the new minimum, if only because that was barely
enough to cover bus fares let alone costs of food and accommodation. Thus
as noted below (see also Levantis, 1997), the great majority of wage-earners
is paid substantially more than the current national minimum wage of K22.96
per week – and even the proposal by the Minimum Wage Board in 2000 to restore
the minimum wage to the 1992 level of K60 per week would not do more than
ratify actual wage levels received by the lowest paid in urban areas.
In effect the
reduction in the urban minimum wage in 1992 from K61.78 per week to K22.96
took it below the “reserve price” of labour, when that includes proceeds
of crime, as suggested by Levantis, whose surveys of 1995 and 1998 also
found that less than 5 per cent of urban workers were aged 20 or under
(2000, p.68). However Levantis’ and his predecessors’ analyses suffer from
the lack of adequate aggregate time series data on employment in PNG -
samples and surveys allow no firm conclusions as to the overall trend.
PNG achieved
an annual average increase in its real GDP between 1974/5 and 2000 of 3.23
per cent p.a., but the rise in the population growth rate to over 3 per
cent p.a. since 1990 has eroded the gains in GDP per head to less than
one per cent p.a., from K610 in 1975 to K727 in 2000, an absolute increase
of K117 or 19 per cent.[5]The
per capita increase would have been greater if population growth had been
less – and that growth belies some commentators’ claims of worsening socio-economic
indicators like infant mortality rates.
The deflators
used to arrive at the constant-price series have not been re-based since
1977, and by 1990 there were significant changes in the composition of
household purchases which according to Gibson would have reduced annual
inflation to 1990 by as much as one per cent (1995, p.36). Using Gibson’s
weights and the sectoral CPI (BPNG, 2000), the all-groups CPI would have
been 5 per cent lower in September 1999, and the data for real GDP in 2000
in Fig.2 would then be understated.
Revised estimates
of GDP for the period from 1993 to 1998 have been issued using (unlike
the BPNG and Treasury series) the 1968 United Nations system of National
Accounts (BPNG, 2000). As the IMF (2000, p.4) has noted, the new series
differs considerably in some years from the previous estimates, showing
a contraction rather than the surprising – given the continuing effects
of the severe drought in 1997 - one per cent growth in 1998 of the latter
(Treasury, 1999, Appendix 2).
The salient
trends evident in the new data on gross national expenditure are the increase
in the share of private consumption, from 56 per cent in 1984 to 63 per
cent in 1998, at current prices, and 60 per cent in 1983 prices (see Fig.3).In
current prices government consumption fell from 20.5 per cent in 1984 to
18.8 in 1998; in constant prices there was a small increase, to 21.5 per
cent. The inevitable counterpart of these trends is the fall in the share
of gross fixed capital formation, from 21 per cent in 1984 to 13.9 in 1998
at current prices, and 13.7 in real. Changes in stocks, which increased,
account for the balance, an indication of the recession that resulted from
the drought in 1997. This fall in investment matches the net outflow of
foreign capital that is evident in the balance of payments since 1994 –
and must raise doubts about the ability of PNG to maintain even its subdued
growth between 1975 and 2000.
However the
new GDP data more encouragingly show an increase in the share of exports,
from 39.6 per cent in 1984 to 50 in current prices in 1998 (real 37.7 to
43.5). The share of imports fell, from over 53 per cent in 1984 to 45.5
in 1998 (real 52.9 to 33.9). Given that 1998 was not a good year for oil
exports, because of low prices, these trends suggest that despite all the
failures in other areas of policy, there has been structural change since
the collapse of the hard Kina in 1994, with the falling share of imports
implying response to the fall in the nominal exchange rate after 1994.
The increase
in the share of exports also suggests that the Kina’s nominal depreciation
since 1994 has been successful in mitigating the Dutch disease effect of
the former deliberately over-valued nominal exchange rate of the Kina,
contrary to expectations that “kina devaluation would elicit little supply
response in the absence of microeconomic reform” (Millett, 1990, Duncan
and Temu, 1995, p.47). Given the inadequacy of micro reform (Weise 2000),
the greater contribution of agriculture than of minerals to export growth
since the Kina was floated in 1994 suggests that the nominal devaluation
did indeed promote some structural adjustment. Chand and Levantis (2000)
use a CGE model to show rather mechanistically that PNG never suffered
from Dutch disease – but the fall in the share of agricultural exports
during the period of the hard Kina and the rise since the Kina was floated
in 1994 suggest there was infection before 1994 and that the IMF and World
Bank were right to press for a market determined exchange rate.
All the same,
comparing the 1993 and 2000 Surveys produces some interesting information
that might have led the Taxation Review (IRC, 2000) to more than just its
largely cosmetic adjustments to income tax scales and rates:
The very large
increase in both the real and the nominal incomes of the upper 22 per cent
of the wage-earning labour force is at least partly due to their relatively
larger increase in productivity, given that they are mostly persons entering
the most productive period of their lives when their lengthening experience
is allied with their superior educational qualifications. The highly paid
are few in number, but contribute disproportionately. Thus tax paid by
the very highest earners was in the 2000 Survey nearly as much as the total
tax paid by all the remaining 99 per cent of taxpayers.
Nevertheless,
the Gini curves shown in Fig. 7 indicate a significant increase in inequality
of both before- and after-tax incomes between 1993 and 2000. Papua New
Guinea’s tax:GDP effort, at around 25 per cent, falls short both of what
is needed to finance its still deficient public health and education services,
and of the tax effort on the donor countries to whom it looks for aid,
even if it compares favourably with most sub-Saharan African countries
(Curtin 2000). The Gini curves suggest there is room for revisiting the
tax schedules in the next Budget, not only to moderate growing inequality
but to raise the revenues needed to enhance public services for the poor.
The 2001 Budget
also implemented the more substantial changes to Papua New Guinea’s mineral
taxation regime proposed by the Taxation Review. This had become critical
following the marked slowing of expenditure on exploration – and the concomitant
absence of new mineral discoveries since the Moran oilfield in 1996. These
included changes to the Additional Profits Tax system (APT) that has been
more of a perceived bugbear than a real threat, with no company ever having
had to pay the tax since its inception.[8]
The new regime could generate some revenue for the first time, offsetting
the tax forgone by the downward revisions to the standard corporate rates,
to 30 per cent from 35 per cent in the case of mining.
The introduction
of Value Added Taxation (VAT) in 1999 was a more radical – and controversial
- move than the changes to direct taxation in the 2001 Budget. Levantis
(2000b) has described the tax as a largely futile exercise, tying
up scarce human resources in the Internal Revenue Commission, with at best
only a zero rather than negative impact on growth of GDP. The World Bank
had long advocated the tax as a means of rationalizing the country’s indirect
taxation, first by replacing the various provincial sales taxes, and second
by substituting for a myriad of tariff rates on imports, as part of the
general reform of the external tariff, which is aimed at eliminating all
protective rates.
The VAT was
intended to be revenue neutral and may eventually increase the share of
indirect revenue total receipts, as has been the case in other countries
that have introduced similar regimes, but early indications are of a net
reduction: in 1998, the last full year before its introduction, the Government
raised K397.8 million in import duties, and the provincial governments
raised and retained their own sales taxes (now abolished) at average rates
of 2-3 per cent (yielding an estimated K100 million). The national Budget
for 2001 expects net collection of K310 million in VAT, and only K85 million
in import duties per se. In practice internal collection difficulties
(apparently many trade stores fail to remit the VAT they collect) have
meant that most VAT collection derives from imports. However the main long-term
benefit of the VAT system, albeit discounted by Levantis (2001), is likely
to be the encouragement to exporters arising from the refund of VAT they
paid on their inputs (if realised, first indications are of late or nil
refunds) – a first straw in that wind is the announcement that Yamaha has
licensed a Papua New Guinea firm Samarai Plastics as a regional manufacturer
for the South Pacific of its fiberglass motor boats (Post-Courier,
21 February 2001).
There followed
a roller coaster period under the Skate government (1997-1999). The national
budget blew out, partly to accommodate large discretionary expenditure
allocations of K1.5 million to each national MP, and the country’s main
commercial bank, PNG Banking Corporation, came under the direction of the
chairman of the largest party in the governing coalition, and increased
its lending by 40 per cent, producing a 30 per cent increase in total private
sector credit in 1998 (Weise 2000, p.3; BPNG, 2000, p.S4). In addition
the World Bank withheld resumption of the SAP because of a dispute over
the government’s appointment of a former Bank official as its economic
adviser (see Curtin 2000a for details).
Realised budget
deficits from 1985 to 2000 (as commonly defined) have been fairly modest
by standards in many other developing countries, mostly (except in 1992
and 1993) within the “good fiscal housekeeping” criterion of the Maastricht
Treaty of the European Union (3 per cent of GDP, see Gupta, 1995, p.6;
and my Table 3). Although PNG would also (just) meet one of the other criteria
for the European monetary union, of public debt at less than 60 per cent
of GDP, its inflation rate (averaging 13 per cent p.a. from1994 to 2000)
and interest rates (bank rates increased from 10 per cent in 1996 to 20
per cent in 1999, and treasury bill rates to 28 per cent) are well in excess
of the Maastrichtceilings, of 3
per cent and 9.8 per cent respectively.
The combination
of the fall in the Kina after 1994 and the high cost of government borrowing
by issuing Treasury bills at up to 28 per cent in 1999 led to a large increase
in the share of external debt servicing in the national budget. The total
cost rose to K656 million in 2000 – amortisation of K488 million was more
than double the level of the early 1990s despite the reduction in the US$
amount of debt outstanding.
PNG’s modest
fiscal rectitude as measured by the deficit:GDP ratio has proven insufficient
for satisfactory economic performance. However the rapid growth of the
money supply since 1995 was not wholly due to fiscal deficits, and it is
that growth which led to most of the pressure on the balance of payments
and the nominal exchange rate. This judgment is confirmed by regression
analysis, showing that if changes in the money supply (M3) are a function
of changes in inflows of foreign exchange (FX) and changes in government
expenditure (G):
dM = aFX + bG + e…..
(1)
then the coefficient
on foreign exchange is significant (t=1.65) and positive (0.26) while that
on government expenditure is negative (-0.2) and insignificant (t = -0.6),
with standard errors of 0.16 and 0.32 respectively, for data covering the
period 1978-1999.
Budgeting in
PNG since 1994 has also been complicated by the combination of large external
debt repayments falling due in the 1990s with the generally low level of
commercial and concessional loans made available to PNG over many years,
and especially since 1990. In the 1990s the Government managed to secure
only one commercial loan, of US$90 million from UBS, and concessional loans
from 1990 to 1998 of only US$500 million (much less than it borrowed in
the 1980s). There was a net reduction in external debt between 1990 and
2000 even after drawings from the SAP loans in 1999 and 2000 (see Table
3).
Perhaps more
important than the budget deficit per se, or the share of public
expenditure in GDP, which is much lower than in the OECD countries, at
less than 30 per cent (see Curtin 2000b), is the qualitative dimension.
This partly relates to the failure of budget allocations to the spending
departments to keep pace with inflation, resulting in scarcity of funds
for basic running expenses, even though public service salaries have also
failed to keep up with inflation. But it is also due to the manifold inefficiencies
in departments’ management of resources that have been discussed at length
by commentators such as Blyth (1994).
Repeated attempts
at “public service reform” have been based on the assumption that all that
was needed was an across-the-board reduction (except for education and
health) in the overall size of the public service, as attempted in the
1999 Budget (see Curtin 2000a). The current IMF/World Bank programme once
again includes public service reform as a key condition, but whilst for
the first time addressing the substantive issues of structure and management,
has failed to insist on ending of appointments to top positions by the
cabinet.
A major source
of qualitative inefficiency is poor cash flow management by the Treasury
department, even without the recent difficulties caused by the no doubt
justified withholding by the IMF/World Bank/Australia of K180 million that
had been committed for payment before the end of 2000, because of slippage
in the government’s compliance with their conditions. The outcome was yet
again an accumulation of arrears from budgeted expenditure commitments
that could not be honoured in the absence of the expected loans, even though
avoidance of such arrears is itself one of the IMF’s conditions. It is
one thing to have budget allocations to key services like health and education
that are in accordance with World Bank guidelines, another entirely if
budget appropriations to provincial education departments, such as the
so-called education subsidies, are paid late if at all as once again in
2001 (these subsidies are the national government’s only contribution to
school running costs other than teachers’ salaries).
It is also fair
to note that the methods by which the Government has financed its deficits
have not been as damaging as they might have been. It had four main options:
1.monetising
the deficit by borrowing at zero cost from the central bank;
2.borrowing
at below market interest rates by coercion of the commercial banks;
3.borrowing
abroad in foreign currency;
4.borrowing
at market interest rates from voluntary domestic private sector
lenders.
Fry (1996, p.7)
notes that the first three impede economic development, and contests Barro’s
version (1989, p.39) of the Ricardian equivalence theorem, that the substitution
of a budget deficit for current taxes has no impact on the aggregate demand
for goods. Only the fourth method “appears to reduce the damaging effects
of any given deficit” -“moving to
this method offers benefits in terms of lower inflation and higher saving
and growth”. This can also be considered a valid method of spreading the
inter-generational costs of public investments that benefit more than just
the present generation as taxes have to be raised in the future to repay
loans raised now in lieu of taxation (Blejer and Cheasty, 1993).
PNG’s deficits
as evident in Table 3 have usually been well within the developing country
mean of 4% and consistent with the OECD median of 3.3% of GDP (Fry, 1997,
p.7). Financing of the deficits has mostly been by a combination of method
(1), borrowing from the central bank, via Treasury Bills issued at market
rates, with method (4), domestic borrowing at market rates. In 1999 and
2000 treasury bill rates were above the prime rates of PNG’s commercial
banks. Thus PNG’s budget deficits have in practice been financed at or
above market rates, partially mitigating the worst monetary effects of
any given deficit. But this market-based financing has led to crowding
out the private sector insofar as the commercial banks have at all times
had excess lending capacity that has not been taken up at the prevailing
level of interest rates.
The underlying
deficits of the 2000 and 2001 Budgets were wholly financed by method (3),
foreign borrowing, in the form of the structural adjustment programme financing
provided by the IMF, World Bank, Australia, and Japan. The adverse effects
of this form of financing are noted by Weise (2000), in the form of future
debt servicing burdens compounded by exchange risks that do not apply to
domestic financing, but are discounted by the central bank, whose policy
is to use structural loans to retire domestic debt (BPNG 2001, p.6).
The aggregate
contribution of the 1999-2001 structural adjustment loans to PNG’s external
debt is very large, at over K1 billion, or about US$375 million (Weise
2000, p.1), amounting to 33 per cent of the previous level of external
public debt. It would require great faith in the productivity of this budget
financing to see it generating at least a fiscal return of 7 per cent p.a.
(i.e. extra tax receipts of K70 million p.a. would be needed to meet the
interest on these loans before repayment of principal).
Successive governments
have striven (in the annual Medium Term Development Strategy produced by
the Ministry of Planning and Implementation) to increase the proportion
of the budget devoted to development (i.e. capital) expenditure. This somewhat
obsolete ambition overlooks the extent to which the recurrent budget contributes
to human capital formation and protection through the education and health
budgets. All the same there has been a significant shift in the share of
the development budget in 2001, to K1 billion, 9.6 per cent of GDP, and
nearly half as large as total recurrent expenditure, but this has in part
been achieved by accounting devices such as treating road maintenance allocations
as capital rather than recurrent spending. What is striking is the still
low level of appropriation for capital works of the traditional kind, such
as new roads, bridges, airfields, power stations, and power transmission
lines. For example, more than a dozen years after completion of the Yonki
hydropower scheme in the north, there is still no transmission line to
Port Moresby in the south, which in consequence increasingly depends on
high cost thermal generation. Similarly, after 25 years of independence
there is still no sealed road link between the national capital and any
of the 13 provincial capitals on the mainland, and food supplies from the
most productive agricultural region of the country can reach the biggest
city only by sea or air.
Monetary
Policy
Those responsible
for monetary policy in Papua New Guinea – since the new Central Banking
Act in 2000 the central bank now has sole responsibility - have faced more
difficult challenges than the framers of the annual budget (BPNG 2001).Their
problems result from the very success of the country’s mineral and primary
industry exporters.
An alternative
to the lack of physical linkages between - and enclave nature of-
PNG’s mineral project areas and the rest of the country would be financial,
with deposits by the resources companies available to underpin lending
by the banking system to the non-mining economy. Very soon after independence
the government took steps to ensure that mining companies banked their
cash balances on-shore. As a concession, and to reduce short-term in and
out flows, the companies were allowed by their Project Agreements to retain
offshore sufficient funds to meet their rolling three-months forward obligations
in regard to offshore interest and dividend payments. In practice, the
obligation to remit cash balances has only aggravated the problems of monetary
policy, by creating a much larger asset base for the commercial banks than
they are able to deploy in loans to the non-mining sector.
Evidence of
lack of lending opportunities includes failure or inability of the banks
either to lend to the limit of the imposed minimum liquid assets ratio
(MLAR), or to lend very much for other than import finance. Australia has
no imposed MLAR, the USA’s legal minimum is 4 per cent (Rose, 1999), yet
Papua New Guinea’s MLAR has never been below 10 per cent, averaging 16.4
per cent from 1980 to 1997 (Meesook, 1997, Table 2.1, and BPNG, 2000),
and 25 per cent since 1999 (implying a deposit multiplier of 4 instead
of 12.5 if the MLAR was 8 per cent). The de facto deposit multiplier
at the end of 2000 was just 1.5 per cent, given the apparent inability
of the commercial banks to lend to the limit of the MLAR.
Whilst most
commentators as noted above focus on fiscal “indiscipline” as the reason
for the constant pressure on the exchange rate of the Kina, and as the
immediate cause of the floating of the Kina in 1994, the much more compelling
explanation (given the usual primary budget surpluses (i.e. excluding debt
servicing) and overall deficits of less than three per cent of GDP, is
the explosive actual and potential lending capacity of the very large liquid
assets generated by the cash balances of the mining and oil companies.
In the absence
of lending opportunities for investment in production or construction of
housing in the domestic economy, it is natural for the banks to concentrate
on lending to finance imports. For the same reason affluent Papua New Guineans
unable to invest in either primary production or building houses in their
home villages, because of the lack of availability of land title, seek
and find more profitable outlets in Queensland, where title is instantly
available.
As a result
lending for home ownership amounted for only K96.2 million (about A$50
million), or only 5 per cent of total bank lending as of September 2000
(BPNG, 2000, p.S13), and bank lending to the agriculture, forestry, and
fishing sector was even less, at K86.9 million, as against net deposits
by the minerals sector of over K300 million. The outcome has been a steady
outflow of capital, despite exchange control regulations that limit individuals
to remitting not more than K50,000 p.a. unless they can demonstrate tax
clearance. In practice, cases that like of a recent Chairman of the National
Provident Fund indicate that well-connected individuals have had no difficulty
in exporting very large sums at will (Post-Courier, 21 February
2001).
At least part
of the outflows of about US$1 billion in 1993-94 before the Kina was floated
in October 1994 would have been repayments of loans used to construct the
Porgera and Misima mines and the Kutubu oilfield and pipeline. But in 1999
the mineral sector accounted for just over half of the total net private
capital outflow of K305 million (Treasury, Budget 2001, vol.1, p.83). For
a developing country like Papua New Guinea to have been a net exporter
of private capital over most of the period since 1992 ought to be of more
concern to the authorities than appears to be the case (see BPNG, QEB
March 1999, for an analysis of equity inflows and outflows).
The irony is
that Papua New Guinea would have little need of external capital if its
banking system was empowered and found opportunities to lend to the prudential
– rather than legal – limits of its liquid assets base. For example, using
the USA’s liquid assets ratio of 4-5 per cent (see Rose, 1999, pp.71-72),
the banks would be entitled to lend up to twenty times more than their
present liquid assets of K1.18 billion as at 29 December 2000, i.e. over
K20 billion, instead of their actual total lending of a mere K1.5 billion,
barely 10 per cent of what would be allowed by the conventional prudential
norm for reserve ratios of 8 per cent.
Although there
are real limitations on lending opportunities due to the lack of land titling,
two major projects where that would not be a problem are not proceeding,
at least partly because of perceived sovereign risks involved in lending
to Papua New Guinea. For in principle the Papua New Guinea banking system
would at its present level of liquid assets - if it were under different
direction - have the capacity to finance both the Kutubu-Queensland gas
pipeline project and the Ramu nickel project, given that these are export
projects that will more than return the foreign exchange costs of their
development.
No doubt in
practice it would also be necessary either to emulate Malaysia’s fixed
exchange rate, at least during the construction phase, or to adopt the
advice of Duncan and Xu (2000) and dollarise the Kina, by readopting the
Australian dollar as the national currency. Dollarisation would in effect
convert the enormous lending potential of Papua New Guinea’s banking system
to “real” money, i.e. from K14 billion to A$7 billion, with MLAR at 8 per
cent, at the current parity of about two for one rather than the one for
one established when the Kina began life in 1975.
Public service
employment amounts to around 1.33 per cent of PNG’s total population, and
the central government wage bill was 8 per cent of GDP in 2000. A World
Bank study (Schiavo-Campo et al., 1999) shows that total government civilian
employment
(excluding police and defence) averages about 4.7 per cent of population
worldwide, ranging from 7.7 per cent in the OEC to 2 per cent in Africa
and 2.6 per cent in Asia. By such measures PNG’s public service is hardly
overblown, nor it is overpaid. Average wages of the PNG central government
employees were K13,000 p.a. in 2000, about six times larger than per capita
income, slightly higher than sub-Saharan Africa’s 5.5 ratio, and more than
the world average of about 3, but that is an indication of low GDP rather
than overblown public services, given PNG’s evident very low ratio of public
servants to population.[10]
PNG’s public
enterprises sector was never as large as in most other developing countries
in Africa and Asia, including its northern neighbour Indonesia, although
there was a tendency to create “corporatised” agencies such as the mainly
donor-funded Small Business Development Corporation. In the 1970s the Government
had acquired shareholdings in various plantations, and it required to be
allocated up to 30 percent of the equity in mineral projects, paid for
by forgone profits in the case of oil but up-front in the case of mining.
The plantation shareholdings were gradually transferred to joint venture
partners in the 1990s, while the government privatized its mineral sector
holdings by the floating of Orogen Minerals Ltd in 1996, in which however
the Government retains a non-voting stake of 50.1 per cent. After the Bougainville
crisis in 1988, the Government assigned up to 10 per cent of its initial
equity in mineral projects (Ok Tedi, Misima, Porgera, Kutubu, and Lihir)
to trust funds representing the respective landowners and charged with
financing social and community projects on their behalf. Assigning equity
to individual landowners (proposed by Duncan and Duncan 1997) who are then
free to dispose of it can create the kind of inter-generation conflict
that was the immediate cause of the closure of the Panguna mine in 1989.
The current
Structural Adjustment Programme requires the Government to implement its
long-declared intent to privatize the five big parastatals (PNG Banking
Corporation, Electricity Commission, Telikom, Air Niugini, Harbours Board).
Already the target date for PNGBC of end-2000 has been missed – but the
Central Bank (BPNG) put it under direct supervision in August 2000. BPNG
was able to do this only after its own independence from government interference
was established by the new Central Banking Act of June 2000 – this in the
long run will prove to have been the most important achievement of the
Morauta government in its first year in office.
The Government
has agreed with the IMF that privatization proceeds will be used to reduce
public debt. However that is a fantasy, as the Prime Minister admitted
in November 2000 that the net worth of all five parastatals is at best
zero, after the years of Indonesian-style management by political appointees
(including his own at PNGBC).
There has been
a tendency in much of the literature on the economy of PNG to single out
“Sole Cause” explanations of its commonly perceived poor performance. For
some it has been lax budgets, others diagnose Dutch Disease, and for Levantis
and Chand (1998) it has been lack of law and order. This paper may suffer
from the same defect, by stressing the obstacles to investment outside
the small area (3 per cent) of the country where individually titled land
tenure is available. No doubt each has played a part, and jointly reinforced
their several negative impacts. For example, although Levantis and Chand
consider that the high potential of PNG for tourism “has been completely
disabled in its development by the law and order problem” (1998, p.10),
both the Dutch disease symptom of an over-valued exchange rate, and the
impossibility of obtaining land title even for resort construction anywhere
in PNG outside the towns and old copra plantations, have been powerful
deterrents to mass tourism[11].
Connell (1997)
concluded his comprehensive study of PNG’s economy with the judgment “neither
growth nor development”. That is a little harsh, for as this paper shows
there has been some economic growth, and even some deepening of development,
such as the evident declining share of the mineral sector’s contribution
to exports and tax receipts, but not as much there might well have been
had land titling been allowed to proceed as proposed by the colonial administration
in 1971. The vacuum created by communal land tenure is filled across most
of the country by foreign loggers with little long-term commitment to the
industry – and prevents deployment of the full value of the credit multiplier
that is available from the asset base of the banking system. Until land
tenure has been reformed, Papua New Guinea is likely to continue to lurch
from one exchange rate crisis to another, however high it keeps its interest
rates, and however closely it conforms to the IMF’s fiscal targets.
Timothy
Curtin
Port Moresby
27 March
2001
Ausaid
(1997) Economic Survey of Papua New Guinea. Australian Agency for
International Development, Canberra.
Axline,
Andrew (1986) Decentralisation and development policy: Provincial government
and the planning process. Institute of Applied Economic and Social
research, Port Moresby.
Blejer,
Mario and Adrienne Cheasty (1993) How to measure the fiscal deficit.
International Monetary Fund, Washington DC.
Blyth,
Conrad (1994) Sustainable Budgets for Papua New Guinea’s economic development.
Institute
of National Affairs, Port Moresby.
BPNG
(1990, 1995, 1999,2000) Quarterly Economic Bulletin, Bank of Papua
New Guinea, Port Moresby.
BPNG
(1998) Money and Banking in Papua New Guinea. Bank of Papua New
Guinea, Port Moresby.
BPNG
(2001). Semi-annual Monetary Policy Statement. Bank of Papua New
Guinea, Port Moresby.
Callick,
Rowan (2000). “PNG at the edge of an abyss”, Australian Financial Review,
9 March 2000.
Connell,
John (1997) Papua New Guinea: the struggle for development. Routledge,
London.
Curtin,
Timothy (1991) Economics of public investment in education in Papua
New Guinea. University of Papua New Guinea, Waigani.
Curtin,
Timothy (1996) Project Appraisal and human capital theory. Project Appraisal,
11(2), 66-78.
Curtin,
Timothy, and E.A.S. Nelson (1999) Economic and health efficiency of education
funding policy. Social Science and Medicine, 48, 1599-1611.
Curtin,
Timothy (2000a) Public sector reform in Papua New Guinea and the 1999 Budget.
Labour
and Management in Development, 1(4).
Curtin,
Timothy (2000b) A new dawn for Papua New Guinea’s economy? Pacific Economic
Bulletin, 15(2), 1-35.
DFP
(1986). National Manpower Assessment 1982-1992. Department of Finance
and Planning, Wards Strip.
Department
of Industrial Relations (1997). Labour Statistics in Papua New Guinea.
Government of Papua New Guinea, Boroko.
De
Soto, Hernando (2000). The Mystery of Capital. Bantam Press, London.
Dorney,
Sean (2000). Papua New Guinea. People, politics, and history since 1975.
Australian Broadcasting Corporation, Sydney.
Duncan,
Ron and Ila Temu, (1995a). Papua New Guinea: longer term developments
and recent economic problems. Asian-Pacific Economic Literature,
9, 2, 36-54.
Duncan,
Ron and Ila Temu, (1995b). The need for fiscal discipline. Pacific
Economic Bulletin, 10(10, 14-18.
Duncan,
Ron and Rod Duncan (1997). Improving security of access to customary-owned
land in Melanesia: mining in Papua New Guinea, in Larmour 1997
Duncan,
Ron and Xinpeng Xu (2000). Should Papua New Guinea adopt a stronger exchange
rate regime? Pacific Economic Bulletin, 15(2), 36-45.
Filer,
Colin (1997) Compensation, rent, and power in Papua New Guinea, in Toft
(1997).
Fry,
Maxwell J (1997) Emancipating the Banking System and developing markets
for Government Debt. Routledge, London.
Garnaut,
Ross, M. Wright, and R. Curtain (1977). Employment, Incomes and Migration
in Papua New Guinea towns. IASER, Port Moresby.
Garnaut,
Ross, Paul Baxter, and Anne Krueger (1983). Exchange rate and macro-economic
policy in independent Papua New Guinea. Department of Finance, Port
Moresby.
Garnaut,
Ross (1995). Monetary stability or more devaluation? Pacific Economic
Bulletin, 10(1), 19-24.
Garnaut,
Ross (2000). The first 25 years of searching for development. Pacific
Economic Bulletin, 15(2), Supplement, 29-36.
Gibson,
John (1995). Food consumption and food policy in Papua New Guinea. Institute
of National Affairs, Port Moresby.
Graham,
Bryan S. (1998). Economic growth in Papua New Guinea: some empirical evidence.
Pacific
Economic Bulletin, 13(2).
Gupta,
Desh (1995). Current economic trends. Pacific Economic Bulletin,
10(1), 3-17.
IMF
(2000). Papua New Guinea. Recent Economic Developments. International
Monetary Fund, Washington DC.
IRC
(2000). Report of the Taxation Review. Internal Revenue Commission,
Port Moresby.
Jones,
L.T.and P.A. McGavin (2000) Creating
economic incentives for land mobilisation in Papua New Guinea. Institute
of National Affairs, Port Moresby.
Larmour,
Peter (editor) (1997). The Governance of Common Property in the Pacific
Region. National Centre for Development Studies, Canberra.
Larmour,
Peter (editor) (1998). Governance and reform in the South Pacific.
National Centre for Development Studies, Canberra.
Lea,
David (1997). Melanesian Land Tenure in a Contemporary and Philosophical
Context. University Press of America, Maryland.
Lea,
David (2000). Dependency theory and its relation to problems of development
in Papua New Guinea. Pacific Economic Bulletin, 15(2), 106-120.
Levantis,
Theodore (1997). The urban labour market of Papua New Guinea, post de-regulation.
Pacific
Economic Bulletin, 12(2): 54-72
Levantis,
Theodore (2000). Papua New Guinea: Employment, wages, and economic development.
Asia Pacific School of Economics and Management, Canberra.
Levantis,
Theodore (2001a). Indirect tax reform and the VAT in Papua New
Guinea. Institute of National Affairs, Port Moresby.
Mawuli,
Agogo, and Zulai, Romeo (1993) Small business employment in Port Moresby,
in Millett (1993).
McGavin,
P.A. and M.A. Ross (1988) Rates of return to investment in education
in Papua New Guinea. Institute of National Affairs, Port Moresby.
McGavin
(1991) Wages, Incomes, and Productivity in Papua New Guinea. Institute
of National Affairs, Port Moresby.
McGavin.
P.A. (1997). Labour Resource Utilisation in Melanesia. National
Centre for Development Studies, Canberra.
Meesook, Kanitta (1997) Financial sector developments 1980-1996, in Temu (1997).
Millett, John (1990) Private sector development in Papua New Guinea. Institute of National Affairs, Port Moresby.
Millett, John (1992) Industrialisation in Papua New Guinea: unrealized potential? Institute of National Affairs, Port Moresby.
Millett,
John (editor) (1993) Seminar on Employment, Agriculture, and Industrialisation.
Institute of National Affairs, Port Moresby.
Mulina,
Rupa (1997). Growth with stability: monetary and fiscal policy in Papua
New Guinea, in Temu (1997).
NSO
(1997). Papua New Guinea. Demographic and Health Survey 1996. National
Statistics Office, Waigani.
Pourhosseini,
M. (editor) (1994). Papers and Proceedings of the National Employment
Summit. National Library Service of Papua New Guinea and United Nations
Development Programme, Port Moresby.
Rose,
Peter S. (1999) Commercial Bank Management. Irwin McGraw Hill, Boston.
Schiavo-Campo,
Salvatore, Giulio de Tommaso, Amitabha Mukherjee (1999) An International
Statistical Review of Government Employment and Wages. World Bank (mimeo),
Washington DC.
Temu,
Ila (editor) (1997). Papua New Guinea: a 20/20 Vision. National
Center for Development Studies, Canberra.
Treasury,
Department of (1998, 1999, 2000). Budget Documents 1999, 2000, 2001.
Port Moresby.
Trebilcock,
Michael and Knetsch, Jack (1981). Land policy and economic development,
Melanesian
Law Journal, 9, 102-115.
Toft,
Susan (editor) (1997). Compensation for Resource Development in Papua
New Guinea. National Centre for Development Studies, Canberra.
Weise,
Daniel (2000). Impact of financial sector reform on business in PNG. Papua
New Guinea Institute of Accountants, Port Moresby (mimeo).
World
Bank (1998) Papua New Guinea. Education sector study. IBRD, Washington
DC.
World
Bank (1999). Papua New Guinea. Country Brief. IBRD, Washington DC.
World
Bank (2000a). Papua New Guinea at a glance. IBRD, Washington
DC
World
Bank (2000b). Report and recommendation of the President: Governance
Promotion Adjustment Loan to the Independent State of Papua New Guinea.
IBRD, Washington DC
World
Bank (2000c). World Development Indicators. IBRD, Washington
DC
Sources:
GDP at 1983 prices (old series) 1983-1998: BPNG 1998; GDP 1999: Treasury
2000. Employment, BPNG 1998, 2000.
Source: Quarterly Economic Bulletin,
September 2000, BPNG.
Source:
World prices – The Economist; PNG CPI and exchange rate, Quarterly Economic
Bulletin, BPNG, 1995, 2000.
Source: Internal Revenue Commission
1993, 2000 (unpublished spreadsheets)
Source: World
Bank 2000c