(individual land ownership) confers a number of definite rights: principally the right to use the land, the right to exclude others from its use and enjoyment; the right to transfer it by sale, lease, or gift; and, perhaps most notably the right to receive income from the property independent of use. This particular combination of rights – use, exclusion, alienation, and income – does not occur in any Papua New Guinea society.
Ironically, in 2000 every single Papua New Guinean man, woman, and child could have been allocated title to 8.8 hectares, for Papua New Guinea has a land area of over 452,000 sq. kilometres, not to mention its very large oceanic area between and beyond its hundreds of islands, and a population in 2000 of just over 5.1 million. This implies a crude population density of about 11 persons per sq.km. (i.e. per 100 hectares), up from 6.5 in 1980, but still very low compared with Indonesia’s 114, if not with Australia’s 2. To be sure, much of PNG’s terrain is mountainous and some coastal areas of the mainland are swampy, but compared with say Afghanistan, with its 27 million people in 640,000 sq.km. of equally rugged but arid mountains (a density of 40 per 100 hectares, i.e. 2.5 hectares of desert per person), PNG’s land endowment cannot be considered either small or ill-favoured. Indeed, with the average family household comprising 5-6 persons, the land availability per household is about 45-50 hectares, almost all of it well wooded, with large potential for expansion of tree crop production, many unexploited arable areas that are also suitable for intensive livestock production, and all generally within relatively short distances of clean running water, although that becomes problematic in (the relatively infrequent) drought years[1].
Yet despite the evident plentiful availability of land per se, almost none of it is available for purchase for agricultural, commercial, or residential purposes, and there is as a result a serious shortage of land (Ploeg, 1999). One potent sign of PNG’s land scarcity is the extraordinary absence across the country of both modern housing in general, except in the towns, and of large-scale tourist resorts in particular.
The low levels of mortgage financing for homes in PNG are discussed below. In the case of tourism, while PNG’s long southern coastlines face part of the Great Barrier Reef, and other similar reefs with world-renowned diving possibilities, there is but a single tourist resort (Loloata Island) that exploits this resource, in contrast to both the hundreds on the other side of the reef in northern Queensland and to the dozen or tourist resorts that have been developed on PNG’s northern coast and the New Guinea islands, where there is access to alienated land, mostly on former copra plantations. Self-evidently, PNG’s southern coastline provides little access to the credit secured against title that is usually necessary to develop the infrastructure for tourism.
The lack of development of PNG’s tourist potential, which is as great in the highlands as along the coastline, results in total annual inflows of foreign visitors (including business visitors) of less than 40,000, compared with Kenya’s 500,000 or Australia’s 2.5 million. Tourist resorts are labour intensive, create markets for local farm produce, and provide income opportunities for cultural groups.
But of more immediate importance perhaps, if land ownership were clearly demarcated, it would greatly facilitate both the development of PNG’s still largely untapped mineral resources and the more equitable distribution of the royalties and compensation payments required of the developers. Disputes between putative landowners - many of whom were new arrivals in the project areas whose claims could not easily be contested by residents who had no evidence to support their own claims- helped to delay some projects (e.g. the Gobe and Moran oilfields) and prevent others (Mount Kare goldfield) (Filer, 1997; Ballard 1997, p.55).
Holzknecht (1999:
144) excuses the opposition to land reform by contending that “it cannot
be overemphasized how important land is for individual and group identity,
survival, continuity, security, and well-being in PNG: to be landless is
to be a person without roots, without merit, unpredictable, and undependable,
a tripman” (Pidgin for a drifter). Yet whatever the psychic and
cultural benefits Papua New Guineans derive from their land, there is no
doubt that the income it yields them under present arrangements is not
impressive and is indeed falling, certainly in terms of cash incomes from
crops like copra, cocoa and coffee, and quite possibly also in terms of
food consumption per head.
That is certainly
not the case in and around the great oil palm plantations in New Ireland,
West New Britain, Milne Bay, and Oro Provinces. The casual visitor to these
can hardly fail to be impressed by the evident prosperity of the neighbouring
villages, based not only on supply of labour to the estates, although much
of that tends to be from other parts of the country/province, but on their
own production of oil palm and on the general economic activity underpinned
by the estates.
It is also suggestive
that oil palm is the only tree crop to have increased output consistently
faster than the population growth rate (Fig.1B). But two-thirds of PNG’s
palm oil is grown by foreign companies (3 British, one Malaysian, one Belgian)
on alienated land, and the balance by smallholders – and many of these,
notably in West New Britain, also own their land. There are some small-scale
outgrowers working customary land and supplying fresh fruit bunches to
the estates’ mills in Milne Bay, Oro, West New Britain, and New Ireland,
but they depend heavily on the estates for a range of services as well
as access to mills which are of course all on alienated land, and their
productivity even so falls well short of the nucleus estates’, by as much
as four times in the case of Milne Bay (Koczberski et al. 2002: 21). The
five estates mostly occupy land alienated for copra or cocoa estates during
the German and British colonial periods, i.e. pre-1914.
Believers in
the development potential of customary land have yet to explain why there
has been no attempt by its “owners” to organise palm oil production in
other feasible areas (e.g. East New Britain, East Sepik and Madang). They
could build their own milling facilities, perhaps using the incorporated
land groups (“ILG”) offered by Holzknecht as an alternative to land alienation,
to raise finance, but as explained by Lea (2001), such groups may well
fare no better than individuals offering only their customary land rights
as collateral to banks (see below). Moreover Henao (2001) has documented
how all too often as many as five ILGs claim to have title to the same
land.
Similarly, PNG’s
landowners have failed to develop their livestock resources to their full
potential. Hide (2002:19,84) has documented the low productivity of the
country’s pig industry, citing Gibson and Rozelle (1998:19) who estimated
a rural production figure of 60,000 tonnes a year in 1996, from a total
stock of about 1.8 million animals, valued at K243 million. This does not
compare well with Australia’s annual output of 370,000 tonnes p.a. from
a total stock of 2.6 million animals in 1999 valued at K1.4 billion Kina
(ABS 2001: 641-3).
Logging is the
only other of PNG’s primary industries to have grown more rapidly than
the population (Fig.1B), and then only until 1996. Since the World Bank
obliged the government to impose penal taxation on log exports in 1996,
logging exports have also fallen like exports of all other crops apart
from palm oil (Hunt 2002). As with oil palm, it is foreign companies, mostly
Japanese and Malaysian, which play the leading role. These companies operate
under licences issued by the Government, nominally with the approval of,
or in association with, local “landowners”. The licences are a form of
lease, but do not constitute transfer of ownership of the logging areas,
and that in itself is enough to inhibit the loggers from replanting trees
whose useful life would only emerge after their licences expired.
Various reports
(for citations see Holzknecht, 1999, p.147) have revealed the extent of
malpractice in the logging industry, beginning with the bribing of successive
Ministers for Forestry and their departmental heads to secure licences,
through breaches of permit conditions and transfer pricing to avoid PNG
taxes, to exceeding sustainable cuts, and “persistent manipulation of resource
owners (sic)”. Holzknecht’s final point should have undermined his faith
in customary land tenure, since the history of logging in PNG is one of
failure by the putative owners of the resource to establish their rights
and secure an equitable distribution of the industry’s profits, because
of their inability to prove their title to any given area (Filer,1997).
In short, the
problem has been that the “resource owners” have had no proof of their
own ownership rights, so that the logging companies were free to treat
with a range of so-called landowner companies that had no legal title but
represented themselves as the “resource owners”, when in reality they were
no more than the satraps of local politicians: “agreements about access
to resources were made behind closed doors, with very little if any broad
consultation with the majority of resource owners, (and the landowner companies)
inevitably side with the loggers against their own people” (Holzknecht,
1997b, p.98; 1999, p.149). As a result the royalties and other devolved
benefits due from the licensees do not reach the customary residents of
the affected areas who are the putative “landowners”.
Another indicator
of the poor development outcomes in PNG’s logging industry is a tendency
for population growth to be slower in the main logging areas than it is
in the census districts where mines or oil palm estates operate on alienated
land. Western Province is a case in point, with the fastest population
growth in the North Fly district that hosts the Ok Tedi mine, and the slowest
in the Middle and South Fly Districts where the loggers have moved in.
Similarly in West Sepik, where the only significant commercial activity
is a large logging project, population growth since 1980 is well below
the national average (NSO, 2001). In the absence of title or long-term
leases, loggers there have had little incentive to replant logged-out areas
with the plantation timber that is necessary to sustain the large-scale
capital investment needed to establish a timber processing industry with
its significant labour requirements. By contrast PNG’s until recently only
plantation and timber processing industry, in Bulolo, largely accounts
for the growing density of population in the Bulolo valley.
The limitations of subsistence food production are
illustrated by the Western Highlands survey: some hundreds of families
in each district were asked in 1982/3 what they had eaten the previous
day: in a typical district 97 per cent reported eating sweet potato, 15
per cent banana, 5 per cent taro, 2 per cent cassava, 2 per cent fish,
and 24 per cent ate rice (Hide et al., 1995, p.25). All except the
rice was grown locally. Apparently no meats or poultry were consumed, and
apart from pork, reserved for special feasts, virtually none is produced.
Duncan and Temu suggested (1995, p.37) that the value of subsistence production in the national accounts is under-estimated, for example, at only K396 million in 1989, and that it is likely to contribute more than half of agriculture’s share of GDP. Gibson and Rozelle confirm this view by indicating a value of total rural household food production of K1.3 billion in 1995 (1998, p.19). But that apparently large amount reduces to only K362 per person of PNG’s rural population in 1995, i.e. less than one Kina per person per day (equal to US$0.70 in 1995, and less than the US$1.00 per person per day considered by the World Bank to be the bare minimum for survival).
Holzknecht argues
that the existence of food production on customary land is enough “to refute
economists’ claims that customary land tenure can be seen only as a severe
impediment to development activities” when he mentions what he regards
as the “extremely high value” of food production to supply urban markets
and of cash crops like betel-nut (1999, p.146). But the only specific data
he mentions is an estimate of the gross value of betel-nut production of
about US$4.5 million in 1995 (then about K6.4 million) in Central, Morobe,
and East New Britain provinces (the main producers). This is an important
and valuable crop for the communities concerned, but after adjusting for
costs, the net income from betel-nut translates to a per person figure
in those provinces’ total population of perhaps K3-5. Holzknecht’s “extremely
high value” of rural food production was, as noted above, estimated by
Gibson at only K1.3 billion in 1995, or less than one Kina per head of
the total rural population. Thus in reality
the available evidence provides scant support for Holzknecht’s view that
customary tenure has not prevented development of the rural economy.
It was noted
above that PNG’s customary landowners have failed to respond to opportunities
for growing the world’s most profitable food crop, palm oil, except where
they live in proximity to a foreign estate and mill. Another possibility
for these landowners is the large potential for both red and white meat
production. PNG’s annual consumption of red meat (beef, sheep, and goat)
has trebled over the last twenty years, growing at 6 per cent p.a., to
about 52,000 tonnes of cwe (carcass weight equivalent), but almost the
whole increase has had to be met by imports, amounting to 41,800 tonnes
in 1998. Domestic production is dominated by commercial producers on alienated
land, such as Ramu Sugar. “Expansion of red meat production would lessen
import requirements and save foreign exchange” (Vincent and Low, 2000)
– as well as providing gross income of K130 million (the value of imports
in 1998), an amount double the estimated value of commercial betel-net
production reported by Holzknecht.
Red meat demand is mostly for sheep meat, but PNG
is not well suited for sheep, despite attempts in the Eastern Highlands.
Suitable areas of grassland exist to allow for much larger production of
beef, but this requires bigger holdings than most smallholders have access
to, and clear property rights over herds. Goats, well suited for smallholder
production, are a possibility but have not been widely adopted. PNG has
maintained self-sufficiency in pork production – but has evidently failed
to develop commercial production sufficiently to compete with imported
beef for a bigger share of the total increase in meat consumption. For
as shown in Table 1, pig meat’s share of total estimated meat consumption
in PNG has fallen from 53 per cent in 1980 to 20 per cent in 1998. The
Table indicates the failure of PNG smallholders to respond to the significant
opportunities for commercial sales from their main livestock resource.
Percentages
|
|
|
|
Beef
|
|
|
|
Sheep meat
|
|
|
|
Poultry
meat
|
|
|
|
Pig meat
|
|
|
|
Total
|
|
|
|
- Total,
in tonnes of cwe
|
|
|
|
Source: Vincent
and Low (2000).
Note:Domestic
production accounts for about 15-18 per cent of beef consumption; while
almost all sheep meat is imported; all goat meat consumption is locally
produced; PNG is self-sufficient in poultry, which was protected first
by an import ban and then by prohibitive tariffs, and in pig meat. There
are no estimates for production of sheep, goat, poultry, and pig meat for
own (i.e. subsistence) consumption since 1980.
Anton Ploeg offers rather different arguments against
the hypothesis that “the continued existence of customary land tenure,
in other words the lack of registered land rights, especially individual
ownership and leasehold, is a main factor hampering growth” (1999, p.165).
First he notes that the adoption of cash cropping by PNG’s subsistence
farmers did not lead to any significant change in techniques, apart from
the adoption of steel tools in place of tools made from sticks and stones,
which continued to be based on manual labour and employed little capital:
“accordingly labour productivity is restricted [and] production requires
relatively much time which limits the expansion of cash cropping” (p.178).
However this lack of adoption of labour saving equipment of all kinds,
of which water pumps are an obvious example, that would be the norm in
say Queensland or even any Australian suburban garden, is itself as much
a symptom of the land tenure regime as an explanation for the continuing
low productivity of PNG agriculture.
Secondly, Ploeg
notes that the amount of land where individuals can have secure customary
rights within their existing villages is limited, because land is parcelled
out in small lots, and new lots can only be acquired at some distance from
existing settlements, adding to walking time between plots (p.178). Claims
on such new areas may be contested and lead to disputes, which explains
the prevalence of unused land through much of PNG’s rural areas. Moreover
since inheritance systems exclude primogeniture, there is a tendency towards
fragmentation of existing household plots. When even some households’ larger
aggregate holdings comprise many small and scattered plots, the scope for
economies of scale with equipment of any kind becomes limited.
Thirdly, Ploeg
emphasizes the continuing importance of ceremonial activities, which pre-empt
not only labour time but also any cash derived from crops (p.179). This
militates against accumulation of savings for the purposes of investment
in lieu of consumption.
Clearly Ploeg
(p.181) and Holzknecht (above, p.bb) are right that it is far from certain
that changing land tenure would be enough to create the conditions for
increasing output and productivity in PNG’s rural sector. Yet experience
elsewhere, starting with Europe, but including African countries like Egypt
(since 1952) and Kenya (since1955), suggests that their pessimism may be
unwarranted.
Holzknecht recognizes (1999, p.153) that PNG’s forests
are like “the commons”, i.e. the land that in Europe was not enclosed and
transferred to private ownership until the second half of the last millennium,
and so was in principle available to all for grazing and other purposes,
leading to degradation and far lower productivity than was achieved after
enclosure and alienation. The phenomenon known as ‘the tragedy of the commons’
arises when the users of common land for grazing (or in PNG’s case, for
logging) have every incentive to maximize their own utilisation of the
resource since they need contribute nothing to the costs of maintaining
it, the end result being its ruination (Jones and McGavin, 2000, p.28).
Holzknecht discounts
the role of the enclosures in raising agricultural productivity in Europe,
claiming that in England it resulted only “in a flood of landless people
into urban areas, thus providing cheap labour to fuel the industrial revolution”
(p.154). This stereotype of the enclosure movement is far removed from
reality, and ignores the huge increase in agricultural productivity, whilst
“the flood of landless people” arose from the reductions in infant mortality
in families settled on enclosed land, which in conjunction with primogeniture
inheritance that meant younger sons had not much to hope for if they stayed
at home (Armstrong 1989, p.657).
Kenya’s land
registration and titling programme was the inspiration behind the Australian
government’s belated and unavailing attempts to promote land tenure reform
in PNG in the years shortly before independence was granted in 1975 (Rowton
Simpson et al., 1971). Prior to 1955 land tenure in Kenya had much
in common with customary systems in PNG. Thereafter the colonial government
combined a programme of land registration and consolidation in the customary
land areas with resettlement of African farmers on former white-owned farms,
and this was continued at an accelerated rate by Jomo Kenyatta’s government
(1964-1977) (Hazlewood, 1979; see below).
The outcome
was an explosion of production of both old and new crops by Kenya’s formerly
purely PNG-type subsistence farmers. Particularly striking was the emergence
of small-scale dairy farming in the newly tenured areas, with enough milk
produced to support the government’s free school milk programme in the
country’s cities by the late 1970s, but this has received less attention
than the large increases in Kenya’s smallholders’ production of coffee
and tea. A key factor was the large provision of credit that became possible
with the establishment of title (Okoth-Ogendo, 1980, 333-337). The data
in Table 2 on production of coffee and tea in Kenya in the 1970s shows
how smallholders accounted for a rising share of the rapid growth of coffee
production in Kenya between 1964 and 1976.Smallholders
dominated PNG’s coffee production by 1975, when they accounted for two-thirds
of total production, but expansion since then has been slow, as implied
by Fig1.A (Fleming and Anthony, 1993, p.52).
Table
2 Production of coffee and tea, Kenya and Papua New Guinea
Sources: Hazlewood
1979; BPNG 1998, 2001 It would be
wrong to imply that changing land tenure changed everything in Kenya, least
of all the propensity to governmental corruption, as endemic there as in
PNG. One of the emerging problems from the 1980s onwards was that unreformed
inheritance laws led in practice to breaking up of the titled smallholdings
to accommodate burgeoning numbers of inheritors. Nevertheless
Kenya’s agricultural production contrasts vividly with PNG’s. In 1980 its
food imports were 8 per cent of total imports, while PNG ‘s were 21 per
cent. Kenya’s food and beverage exports were 44 per cent of its total exports
in 1980, and 59 per cent in 1998 (latest available year); PNG’s were 23
per cent in 1980 and 23 per cent in 1999 (dropping back from 27 per cent
in 1998 after the recovery in oil prices in 1999) (World Bank 1987, 2000;
BPNG 2001). Egypt’s land
reform from 1952 involved breaking up large estates and providing hitherto
landless peasants (“fellah”), who had previously in the main been tenant
farmers, with title to their new holdings (Mabro, 1974, pp.56-63). In fact
Egypt’s land reforms in the sense of moving to individual tenure had begun
in the previous century, and the 1952 land redistribution was firmly based
on individual title. It was accompanied by a large increase in the provision
of rural credit and the development of a cooperative movement, essential
when ninety per cent of holdings consisted of one hectare or less. The
outcome was dramatic increases in agricultural productivity, despite the
fall that might have been expected from the additional annual cropping
permitted by the Aswan High Dam, with yields per hectare of most crops
rising by at least 50 per cent between 1951 and 1971 (Mabro, p.81). Above
all Egypt demonstrates that individual land tenure is compatible with maintaining
equity, by the use of legislation limiting the maximum size of holdings,
contrary to Holzknecht’s equations that customary tenure equals equity
and that individual tenure equals monopolization of all land by a few (draft
chapter, p.7). Establishing
a fully juridical system of land tenure in PNG, with enforcement of repossessions
in case of mortgage defaults, would in all likelihood greatly increase
banks’ willingness to lend, and development of cooperatives would also
be helpful (they played a leading role in Kenya’s smallholder coffee sector
- and in Tanzania’s until abolished by Juliuus Nyerere in the 1970s). By
contrast, PNG’s commodity boards have in some cases served only to expropriate
growers’ surpluses in times of high prices, and have at best been more
concerned with price stabilization than with expanding their clients’ production
(Fleming 2001). PNG’s banks
in September 2001 had liquid assets equal to 37 per cent of their lending,
well above PNG’s very high legal minimum of 30 per cent – the norm in developed
countries is around 8 per cent (BPNG, 2001). Were collateral available,
the banks would no doubt lend more for agriculture – and the BPNG might
well then be able to lower the liquidity ratio, since unlike most of the
banks’ lending, loans to the rural sector would relieve the country’s balance
of payment restraint, by reducing food imports and raising exports. The German development
agency GTZ has acted on de Soto’s ideas (2000) by sponsoring large-scale
registration of illegally built homes in the largest slum in the world’s
most crowded city, Egypt’s Cairo, as a first step towards upgrading both
housing and infrastructure. The residents of Ezbet Bakhit will be able
to buy the land they occupy, and thereby gain access to credit, as well
as start paying taxes (Drummond, 2001). David Lea (2001,
p.39) has discussed the structure of the 1974 Land Groups Incorporation
Act, the enabling legislation for the ILGs advocated by Holzknecht (1997a)
as an alternative to individual land tenure for purposes of raising capital.
Lea quotes James’ description of the Act as “lineage clothed with legal
personality” and retaining key elements of the customary land system, such
as “collective ownership, mass participation in the decision making processes,
traditional disputes settlement philosophy, and a distribution system based
on one’s interest in the land” (1985, p.50). That description almost fits
a modern company or corporation, with its collective ownership by shareholders,
their enfranchisement at annual meetings that appoint directors and determine
profits distribution in proportion with one’s interest in the company.
What the ILG lacks is the company’s liability to be bankrupted and lose
its corporate assets (but not those of its shareholders) if it fails to
manage them effectively. That penalty for failure provides the element
of accountability that de Soto (2000, p.47) has emphasized as crucial to
the development process – and that was so signally lacking in the lending
operations of the Rural Development Bank as also in PNG’s rural sector
as a whole. The unwillingness
of much of rural society to contemplate the possibility of mortgage sales
of estates and farms that have failed to service their debts largely explains
the decision of PNG’s banks to walk away from rural lending even to formerly
colonial enterprises working alienated land that are now in national hands.
The Waghi Mek coffee estate was a rare success story of a landowner company
able to raise large bank loans because it had title – but that success
excited the envy of adjacent communal “landowners” lacking title to their
own holdings who claimed possession of Wahgi Mek by force in 2000. Such
actions both explain the reduction in lending to agriculture evident in
Table 3 – and indicate the need for comprehensive rather than piecemeal
land reform (see below). But clearly the ILG model could if adapted to
accommodate the principle of limited liability of its members as primarily
owners of ground rents, whilst encompassing the possibility of losing its
leaseholder rights over their land, approximates to modern corporations.
This was indeed broadly the concept behind the tentative proposals for
land reform, put forward on behalf of the Minister for Lands by Henao (2001),
which led to the student riots on the streets of Port Moresby in July 2001. facturing truction Source:
BPNG (Quarterly Economic Bulletin). Notes:
Data is for March, usually the month when seasonal loans to agriculture
are at their peak. “Other” mostly comprises loans to other businesses,
the government, and non-housing loans to individuals. It may therefore be helpful to describe how individual
land tenure was achieved elsewhere, despite all the above problems, first
in 1778 in the present writer’s ancestral village of Wedmore, in Somerset,
England, and secondly around 1960, in Kenya, where almost identical problems
were successfully dealt with. The most important point is that contrary
to the apparent belief of some of PNG’s opponents of land reform, in neither
case was any person dispossessed of any part of his customary land, even
if subsequently as a matter of choice the land awarded was sold or otherwise
disposed of.
Agricultural Credit in Papua New Guinea
Mortgage Lending in Papua New Guinea
Table 3 Commercial Banks’ Outstanding Advances by Sector
1994-2001
A guide to implementing land reform in Papua New Guinea
Thus in Wedmore
in 1778, a large majority of the village’s customary landowners themselves
applied to the Parliament in London for an Act enclosing Wedmore Moor,
being the common land to the east of the village (its other surrounding
moors were dealt with later).[2]The
Act made a total of 258 awards of customary tenements within the Moor to
some 168 individuals (some obtained more than one allotment, in accordance
with their acquired customary rights) (Rose 1982, 20-26). This writer’s
distant relative William Stone was one of those “allotted and awarded”
full title to his “tenement” (i.e. parcel of land to which he had customary
rights), as defined by survey and measuring two acres (about 0.8 hectares).
The Act also allotted several tenements of two acres each to William’s
brother Benjamin, his cousin Gabriel, and his aunt Mary Stone. In return
for granting them title, the Act required the Stones and the other recipients
of awards to maintain and keep in repair “all gates, styles, hedges, mounds,
bridges, fences and watercourses” on their land (Rose, 1982, 72-74). No
persons who had customary rights to any part of the Moor lost their entitlement,
but they did gain the right to sell their – or buy other – allotments.
The population of Wedmore at the 1801 Census, by when the enclosure process
had been completed, was 2,083; but contrary to Holzknecht’s assertion noted
above that the enclosures led to a decrease in rural population, the village’s
population had increased by the 1851 census to 3,865 (Page et
al., 1911, p.341).
The creation
of individual title in Kenya was similar. Again, not only were traditional
rights recognized, but in addition opportunity was taken to consolidate
scattered fragments of land holdings into larger single units, and this
was widely welcomed (Sorrenson, 1967, p.223). Unlike England, where the
enclosures took place gradually over centuries, the process in Kenya’s
highlands was completed within two decades. By 1977 92 per cent of 30 million
hectares (equal to about 66 per cent of PNG’s total area) of total registrable
customary land (i.e. excluding the north-eastern nomadic areas) had been
registered and title granted, amounting to some 1.7 million farms, of which
about half were less than one hectare (Hazlewood 1979, 34-42). As noted
above, the 2000 Census indicated that PNG has about one million households,
so that providing each of them with registered title would not be more
difficult than in Kenya – and as in Kenya, aid donors could be asked to
support the process with expertise and funding.
A key feature
of Kenya’s land reform, unlike England’s, is that it adopted South Australia’s
Torrens system of 1858, whereby registration was compulsory and title was
guaranteed by the State (Sorrenson, 1967, 182-183). This was done to avoid
the complexities of land conveyancing in England and use of the “corrupt”
local courts in Kenya.
Table 2 above
provided data on the Kenyan smallholder’s contribution to production of
coffee and tea. In the case of tea, the area planted increased from 5,100
hectares in 1964 to 43,600 hectares in 1976 (Hazlewood, p.45). In addition
to tea and coffee, smallholders made a notable contribution to sugar production,
accounting for a third of total production of 1.9 million tonnes of sugar
cane in 1977 (Hazlewood, p.45). By contrast, although sugar cane is native
to the country, smallholders scarcely contribute at all to PNG’s commercial
sugar-cane production, which is confined to a single estate that produces
less than a quarter of Kenya’s output.
SUMMARY AND
CONCLUSIONS
Holzknecht and Ploeg amongst others argue that there is no economic necessity for PNG to change its traditional forms of land tenure to modern forms based on alienation, “and making land a commodity to be bought and sold” (Holzknecht, 1999, p.141), “because a high percentage of coffee, cocoa, copra exported from PNG comes from smallholders working on their customary land” (Holzknecht 2002: p.x). The failure shown above of those smallholders to expand output in line with the growth of population is nevertheless prima facie evidence of a case for land reform, evidence that is supported by Holzknecht’s assessment that“some 93% of the poor live in rural areas, where over 41% of the population live below the poverty line” (p. y). Holzknecht’s further comments that “large [sic] tonnages of garden greens and other vegetables - and certainly not all traditional crops – are sold in markets around the country”, and that “the betel-nut market around PNG is likely the highest value annual crop for which there has been developed a most sophisticated marketing network across PNG all without any assistance from the state or from international donors” (p.z), were shown above to be based on inadequate interpretation of the data, as well as being inconsistent with his recognition of the depth of poverty in PNG’s rural areas.
The experiences noted above of land reform in countries as diverse as England, Egypt, and Kenya suggest the potential benefits available in PNG. In particular, the expansion of Kenya’s smallholder production of coffee and tea if replicated in PNG could well have more than doubled the cash incomes of the latter’s smallholders in its highlands. The similar apparent inability of PNG’s customary landowners to respond to the opportunities for cash production of sugar cane and red and white meats also suggests that the problem may lie in land tenure.
Land reform of itself cannot solve
all the problems of development, but it has been part and parcel of success
in so many countries in the rest of the world that it deserves a chance
in Papua New Guinea.
![]() |
![]() |
Australian Bureau of Statistics 2001. Yearbook of Australia 2001. Canberra: ABS.
Ballard, C. 1997 It’s the land, stupid! The moral economy of resource ownership in Papua New Guinea, in Larmour 1997.
Bank
of Papua New Guinea 1998 Money and Banking in Papua New Guinea.
Port Moresby: BPNG
Bank
of Papua New Guinea 2001 Quarterly Economic Bulletin. Port Moresby:
BPNG
Bourke,
R.M., M.G. Allen, J.G. Salisbury 2001 Food Security for Papua New Guinea.
Canberra: Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research.
Burton, J. 1997 The Principles of Compensation in the Mining Industry, in Toft, 1997:116-136
De Soto, H. 2000 The Mystery of Capital. Why Capitalism triumphs in the West and fails everywhere else. London: Bantam Press
Drummond,J. 2001 Freehold provides collateral for a better future. London: Financial Times, 18 October 2001
Duncan,
R. and Ila Temu, (1995). Papua New Guinea: longer term developments and
recent economic problems. Asian-Pacific Economic Literature, 9(2),
36-54.
Filer,
C. (ed.) 1997a The Political Economy of Forest Management in Papua New
Guinea. Port Moresby: NRI; London: IIED.
Filer,
C. 1997b Compensation, rent, and power in Papua New Guinea, in Toft, 1997.
Fleming, E. and G. Anthony 1993 The Coffee Economy in Papua New Guinea. Analysis and Prospects. Main Report. Port Moresby: Institute of National Affairs.
Fleming, E. 2001 The case against reintroducing price stabilisation schemes in Papua Guinea: a study of cocoa. Pacific Economic Bulletin.16(2), 53-62
Gibson, J. and S. Rozelle 1998 Results of the Household Survey Component of the 1996 Poverty Assessment for Papua New Guinea (mimeo).
Gibson, J. 2001 The nutritional status of PNG’s population, in Bourke 2001: 407-413
Harding, Thomas 1973 Land Tenure, in Hogbin 1973.
Hazlewood, A. 1979 The Economy of Kenya. The Kenyatta Era. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Henao, L. 2001 Mobilizing Customary Land Tenure through Customary Land Registration. Port Moresby: mimeo
Hide, R.L., R.M. Bourke, B.J. Allen, D. Fritsch, R. Grau, P. Hobsbawn, and S. Lyon 1995 Agricultural Systems of Papua New Guinea, Working Paper no.10, Western Highlands. Canberra: Australian National University.
Hide, R.L. 2002. Pig Husbandry Systems in New Guinea: a Review. Canberra: ACIAR.
Hogbin, Ian 1973 Anthropology in Papua New Guinea. Melbourne: Melbourne University Press
Holzknecht, H. 1997a Two sides of the coin: the case of forestry, in Toft 1997, 94-104.
Holzknecht, H. 1997b Pro Bono Publico? Conservation and appropriate resources management strategies in Papua New Guinea, in Filer 1997, 368-390.
Holzknecht, H 1999 Customary Property Rights and Economic Development, in van Meijl 1999, 139-164.
Holzknecht, H. 2002 Papua New Guinea Customary Land Issues.
Hunt, C. 2002. Production, privatisation, and preservation in Papua New Guinea forestry. London: IIED.
Killick, T. 1981 Papers on the Kenyan Economy. London: Heinemann.
Koczberski, G., G Curry, K Gibson 2002. Improving productivity of the smallholder oil palm sector in Papua New Guinea. A socio-economic study of the Hoskins and Popondetta schemes. Canberra: Australian National University.
James, R.W. 1985 Land Law and Policy in Papua New Guinea. Port Moresby: PNG Law Reform Commission.
Jones, L.T. and P.A. McGavin 2000 Creating incentives for land mobilisation in Papua New Guinea. Port Moresby: Institute of National Affairs.
Larmour, P. (ed) 1997 The Governance of Common Property in the Pacific Region. Canberra: NCDS, Australian National University.
Lea, D.R. 1997 Melanesian Land Tenure in a Contemporary and Philosophical Context. Lanham: University Press of America.
Lea, D.R. 2001 Resolving the complexity of land mobilisation issues in Papua New Guinea. Pacific Economic Bulletin.16(2), 36-52
Mabro,
R. 1974 The Egyptian Economy 1952-1972. Oxford: Clarendon Press
Mingay,
G.E. (ed.) 1989 The Agrarian History of England and Wales, VI:1750-1850.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Mueller,
I. 2001 The spatial pattern of child growth in PNG, in Bourke 2001.
Muntwiler,
M. and R.M. Shelton 2001 Survey of nutrition and protein intake in rural
families in Eastern Highlands Province, in Bourke 2001.
Okoth-Ogendo, H.W.O. 1980 Land Ownership and Land Distribution in Kenya’s Large Farm Areas, in Killick 1981, 329-338.
Page, W. et al. (eds.) 1911 Victoria History of the County of Somerset. London: Dawsons.
Ploeg, A.1999 Land tenure and the Commercialisation of Agriculture in Papua New Guinea, in van Meijl 1999, 165-185
Rose, C. A. 1982 Wedmore’s Moors and the Enclosure Acts of the 18th Century. Wedmore: Cuthbert Rose
Rowton Simpson, S. and R.L. Hide, A.M. Healy, and J.K. Kinanjui 1971 Land Tenure and Economic Development, New Guinea Research Bulletin 40. Canberra: Australian National University.
Siaguru, Sir A 2001 Land Mobilisation: a Hidden Dimension. Port Moresby: Post-Courier, 14 December 2001.
Sorrenson, M.P.K. 1967 Land Reform in the Kikuyu Country. Oxford: OUP
Toft, S. (ed) 1997 Compensation for Resource Development in Papua New Guinea. Port Moresby: Law Reform Commission; Canberra: NCDS, ANU
Van Meijl, T and F. von Benda-Backman (eds.) 1999 Property Rights and Economic Development: Land and Natural Resources in Southeast Asia and Oceania. London: Kegan Paul.
Vincent, D. and S. Low 2000 A Review of Papua New Guinea’s Red Meat Industry. Canberra: Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research.
World Bank 1987 World Development Report 1987. Washington: IBRD.
World Bank 2000 World Development Report2000-2001. Washington: IBRD.